Showing Latest Publications

The View from Turkey: A TOTM Q&A with Kerem Cem Sanli

TOTM How did you come to be interested in the regulation of digital markets? I am a full-time professor in competition law at Bilgi University in . . .

How did you come to be interested in the regulation of digital markets?

I am a full-time professor in competition law at Bilgi University in Istanbul. I first became interested in the application of competition law in digital markets when a PhD student of mine, Cihan Dogan, wrote his PhD thesis on the topic in 2020. We later co-authored a book together (“Regulation of Digital Platforms in Turkish Law”). Ever since, I have been following these increasingly prominent issues closely.

Read the full piece here.

Continue reading
Antitrust & Consumer Protection

A Holiday Hootenanny Hiatus, But First, Some Title II Talk

TOTM For those of who’ve been doing the Telecom Two-Step over the past year, the holiday break can’t come soon enough. Last week, comments were due . . .

For those of who’ve been doing the Telecom Two-Step over the past year, the holiday break can’t come soon enough. Last week, comments were due on the Federal Communications Commission’s (FCC) latest proposal to impose Title II common-carrier regulation under the guise of net neutrality national security. Before that, we had the FCC’s new and expansive “digital discrimination” rules. Early in the New Year, we’ve got reply comments due on Title II and comments on the FCC’s proposal to ban early termination fees for cable and satellite providers.

The FCC has pushed telecom folks to crank out more content than James Patterson. So, we can be forgiven for pouring ourselves a cup of cheer, turning on “The Muppet Christmas Carol,” and taking a brief hiatus.

Read the full piece here.

Continue reading
Telecommunications & Regulated Utilities

The Necessity of a Consumer Welfare Standard in Antitrust Analysis

Popular Media In a previous article, we refuted four common critiques of the consumer welfare standard (CWS). In this article, we argue that the CWS has key benefits . . .

In a previous article, we refuted four common critiques of the consumer welfare standard (CWS). In this article, we argue that the CWS has key benefits which opponents overlook. Understood as a method rather than a set of goals, the CWS allows enforcers and courts to overcome fact-finding ambiguities inherent in competitive processes. Without the benefit of a consumer welfare standard as a yardstick, alternative frameworks such as “the protection of the competitive process” lack depth, are self-referential and, ultimately, arbitrary.

Read the full piece here.

Continue reading
Antitrust & Consumer Protection

Share Excess Clean Energy Fund Dollars with Portlanders

Popular Media The unexpected $540 million coming to Portland’s Clean Energy Fund should go back to Portlanders (“Portland’s Clean Energy Fund expected to raise additional $540M over . . .

The unexpected $540 million coming to Portland’s Clean Energy Fund should go back to Portlanders (“Portland’s Clean Energy Fund expected to raise additional $540M over next 5 years,” Dec. 13). Since the tax took effect in 2019, consumer prices have increased by about 20%, straining family budgets. The tax on sales underpinning the Clean Energy Fund worsens this strain. If the projections are correct, the clean energy taxes, including the $750 million that was already anticipated as well as this additional bump, amount to more than $900 a year per Portland household. Commissioner Carmen Rubio suggests spending half of the new windfall to boost the budget of cash-strapped city bureaus. She should send the other half back to Portland families.

Continue reading
Telecommunications & Regulated Utilities

Posner Meets Hayek: The Elements of an Austrian Law & Economics Research Program

Scholarship Abstract To date, Friedrich Hayek is the only winner of the Nobel Prize in Economics who also holds a law degree. The role of law . . .

Abstract

To date, Friedrich Hayek is the only winner of the Nobel Prize in Economics who also holds a law degree. The role of law is central to Hayek’s work and prominent in the research program of the Austrian School of Economics generally. Although Hayek’s contributions to jurisprudence are manifest, as are the influence of his economics ideas, his influence on the field of law and economics has remained modest. This lecture, delivered as the Keynote Lecture at the 2023 Asian Law & Economics Association Annual Meeting, provides an introduction to the fundamentals of an Austrian Law & Economics research program in contrast to the mainstream, Chicago-school research program that has dominated the field since its early history. Compared to the neoclassical approach, Austrian thinking provides a more insightful approach to many of the key concepts generally associated with the economic analysis of law: the nature and success of the common law as a system of law, the importance of stability and simple rules in the law, and the strong preference for private ordering via contract, personal autonomy, and voluntary exchange exhibited in the common law.

I identify and briefly describe six key distinguishing characteristics of the Austrian school that distinguishes it from neoclassical law and economics: (1) Methodological individualism, (2) utility and costs are subjective, (3) the division of knowledge, (4) spontaneous order, (5) competition as a discovery procedure, and (6) the nature of economic equilibrium. I will also highlight some of the ways in which examining law and economics through an Austrian framework provides valuable insights about law and economics.

Read at SSRN.

Continue reading
Antitrust & Consumer Protection

As Good as Gold? A Framework for Analyzing Redeemable Paper Money

Scholarship Abstract In this paper we present a theory of note discounts, exchange rates between brands of notes, and the price level in convertible paper money . . .

Abstract

In this paper we present a theory of note discounts, exchange rates between brands of notes, and the price level in convertible paper money regimes. We show that under perfect commitment to convertibility, notes and the underlying commodity are perfect substitutes and price level determination is identical to a pure commodity standard. Different brands of currency trade at par. With imperfect commitment to convertibility, the probability that the issuer reneges on the commitment to convertibility explains discounts/premia on notes and exchange rates between brands in competitive note regimes. In non-competitive regimes, the probability of reneging explains fluctuations in the price level. To support our model, we discuss historical events and time periods that are consistent with our theory.

Continue reading
Financial Regulation & Corporate Governance

Comments of Christopher Yoo and Gus Hurwitz to FCC on Safeguarding and Securing the Open Internet

Regulatory Comments We thank the Federal Communications Commission for this opportunity to comment on the rules proposed in the above-captioned Notice of Proposed Rulemaking.[1] We are both . . .

We thank the Federal Communications Commission for this opportunity to comment on the rules proposed in the above-captioned Notice of Proposed Rulemaking.[1] We are both legal academics with long-standing interest in the topics addressed by these proposed rules. Over the past 15 years, we have each published numerous articles, books, and other scholarly works on network neutrality and related topics, submitted comments in relevant Commission proceedings and briefs in related judicial proceedings, and been active participants in academic and public discussion of these topics.[2]

The views presented below are ours alone and should not be attributed to our employer or to the Center for Technology, Innovation, and Competition. Neither of us has received any compensation for these comments, nor has either of us been retained by any party with a financial interest in these proceedings.

The essence of the rules – their purpose and flaws – are effectively captured in the first paragraphs of the NPRM:

  1. Today we propose to reestablish the Federal Communications Commission’s (Commission) authority over broadband Internet access service by classifying it as a telecommunications service under Title II of the Communications Act of 1934, as amended (Act). While Internet access has long been important to daily life, the COVID-19 pandemic and the rapid shift of work, education, and health care online demonstrated how essential broadband Internet connections are for consumers’ participation in our society and economy. Congress responded by investing tens of billions of dollars into building out broadband Internet networks and making access more affordable and equitable, culminating in the generational investment of $65 billion in the Infrastructure Investment and Jobs Act.
  2. But even as our society has reconfigured itself to do so much online, our institutions have fallen behind. There is currently no expert agency ensuring that the Internet is fast, open, and fair. Since the birth of the modern Internet in the 1990s, the Commission had played that role, but the Commission abdicated that responsibility in 2018, just as the Internet was becoming more vital than ever.

While the NPRM would establish various specific rules (e.g., the proposed conduct rules and transparency rule) and puts forth various justifications for them, the primary and most significant goal of the proposal is to classify Broadband Internet Access Service (BIAS) as a Title II telecommunications service. That is literally the first sentence of the NPRM.

This purpose is also the most objectionable and least necessary aspect of the proposed rules. Also as noted in the first paragraph, and discussed in the NPRM, the COVID-19 pandemic made more clear than ever the importance of the Internet to modern life. But unrecognized by the NPRM, this period also demonstrated the extent to which the pervasive regulation contemplated by Title II is unnecessary for the Internet to satisfy this important role. While stressed, and while benefitting from support from programs like the Emergency Broadband Benefit,[3] American Rescue Plan Act,[4] and Affordable Connectivity Program,[5] the Internet proved its importance throughout the pandemic largely by living up to the tasks to which it was unexpectedly put. A lack of Open Internet regulations did not prevent it from doing so.

The first paragraph also recognizes Congress’s investment of $65 billion to support broadband deployment in response to the pandemic.[6] In so doing, Congress tasked an agency other than the Commission, the National Telecommunications and Information Agency (NTIA), with primary responsibility for overseeing use of this funding through the Broadband Equity, Access, and Deployment (BEAD) program.[7] And Congress did not include any network neutrality or open Internet provisions as requirements for allocation of this funding. This calls into substantial question whether Congress views the Commission as the regulatory agency with regulatory authority as relates to the Internet and, especially, whether Congress views rules such as proposed in the NPRM as necessary.

Even to the extent that it is true that the Commission is a relevant expert agency, the assertions in the second paragraph of the NPRM are false. The Federal Trade Commission (FTC) has expertise in antitrust and consumer protection. To the extent that Internet Service Providers (ISP) commit to providing fast, open, and fair service to their users—promises routinely made—there is, in fact, an agency with relevant expertise to ensure those commitments are kept. And to the extent that an ISP does not make such commitments, the First Amendment limits the FCC’s ability to impose them upon the ISP through the proposed rules. And to the extent that the FCC has played that role “since the birth of the modern Internet in the 1990s,” Title II classification has only been the basis for that role for the brief period between adoption of the 2015 Open Internet Order and its recission in the 2018 Restoring Internet Freedom Order.

The Commission is needlessly steering into political controversy through Title II reclassification. The D.C. Circuit’s 2014 opinion in Verizon makes clear that implementation of the substantive rules proposed in the NPRM could be accomplished using the Commission’s Title I authority.[8] There would likely be widespread support for (or at least acceptance of) rules adopted on this basis, both political and from industry.

This concern is heightened by the current judicial landscape. The Supreme Court’s evolving Major Questions Doctrine jurisprudence casts significant doubt on the Commission’s ability to assert long-disclaimed pervasive regulatory authority over Internet services—services that the Commission has repeatedly referred to as of substantial economic and political significance.[9] This is heightened by the changing technology of Internet access, which calls into doubt the ongoing relevance of the analysis in Brand X[10], the most important precedent supporting Title II classification of BIAS.[11] And the Supreme Court is hearing this term cases that bear directly on First Amendment central to the proposed rules.[12] The proposed rules significantly implicate speech regulation and are therefore highly sensitive to changing First Amendment jurisprudence. Proposing rules prior to resolution of these ongoing cases creates a needles risk of uncertainty over the coming years—a risk that directly contradicts the importance that the Commission ascribes to the proposed rules.

The remainder of these comments further develop these concerns in four sections. Part I discusses how technological developments over the past twenty years raise doubt about the continued application of the conclusions in Brand X. Part II looks at the current state of the broadband Internet services industry, focusing on the BEAD Program. Part III looks at First Amendment considerations relating to the NPRM. And Part IV considers the Supreme Court’s recent Major Questions Doctrine jurisprudence.

I. Changes in BIAS Architecture Cast Doubt on Continued Relevance of Brand X

The most important precedent governing classification of BIAS as a Title I information service or Title II telecommunication service is the Supreme Court’s opinion in Brand X. The question in Brand X was, in a sense, the opposite of that presented by the NPRM.

Both involve the classification of broadband Internet service as either an “information service” (regulated under Title I of the Communications Act) or a “telecommunications service” (regulated under Title II of the Communications Act). These terms are defined in 47 U.S.C. 153:

(20) INFORMATION SERVICE.—The term “information service” means the offering of a capability for generating, acquiring, storing, transforming, processing, retrieving, utilizing, or making available information via telecommunications, and includes electronic publishing, but does not include any use of any such capability for the management, control, or operation of a telecommunications system or the management of a telecommunications service.

(43) TELECOMMUNICATIONS.—The term “telecommunications” means the transmission, between or among points specified by the user, of information of the user’s choosing, without change in the form or content of the information as sent and received.

(46) TELECOMMUNICATIONS SERVICE.—The term “telecommunications service” means the offering of telecommunications for a fee directly to the public, or to such classes of users as to be effectively available directly to the public, regardless of the facilities used.

In Brand X, the Court recognized that some portion of the Internet service offered by a cable ISP is a telecommunications service and that some other portion is an information service.[13] The question the Court faced was whether those were so tightly integrated that the entire offering could be classified as a single information service offering, as opposed to separate and distinct telecommunications and information service offerings.[14]

In the proposed rules, the Commission proposes to do the exact opposite: they would classify an offering that includes some amount of information services alongside a telecommunications service as an integrated telecommunications service. While it seems natural to characterize these as obverse sides of a coin, the statutory reality does not allow this approach. The definition of an “information service” is the offering of various capabilities “via telecommunications”—information services are, in other words, necessarily integrated with a telecommunications service. The definition of “telecommunications service,” on the other hand, includes exclusively the provision of telecommunications. Any blending of these services can only be an information service.

If the Commission is to classify BIAS as a Title II telecommunications service, such classification must apply solely to the portion of an ISP’s service that is not an information service. If, in other words, Domain Name System (DNS) services are information services, offering consumers a service that includes DNS access must necessarily fall outside of the scope of BIAS offerings classified as Title II services. The same applies for any other services offered by an ISP that are necessarily information services.

As noted in the NPRM, a similar argument was rejected by the D.C. Circuit Court of Appeals in its affirmation of the 2015 Open Internet Order’s classification of BIAS as a Title II service.[15] There, a two-judge majority accepted the Commission’s characterization of DNS service as relating to the “management, control, or operation of a telecommunications system or the management of a telecommunications service,” features which remove the service from the statutory definition of an information service.[16] Dissenting, Judge Williams would have rejected that argument as arbitrary and capricious.[17]

Even accepting the Commission’s argument, this approach turns the question into a technical one. Judge Williams notes that with this approach “the Commission set for itself a highly technical task of classification”[18]—an echo of the Supreme Court’s statement in Brand X that the question of whether transmission services and DNS service are functionally integrated “turns not on the language of the Act, but on the factual particulars of how Internet technology works and how it is provided.”[19]

The question of whether DNS service is a management, control, or operation function was briefly discussed in Brand X, as well—though it was not properly before or decided by the Court. Rather, it was raised by Justice Scalia in his dissent, to which the majority responded in its footnote 3. In his dissent, Justice Scalia characterizes DNS service as “scarcely more than routing information, which is expressly excluded from the definition of ‘information service.’”[20] In its footnote, the majority notes that “routing information” is not, in fact, among the functions excluded from the definition of an information service.[21] Of course, ISPs do offer routing services. They do not merely transmit information of the user’s choosing between or among points specified by the user without change in the form or content sent or received—they very often select for the user which endpoints to which the user’s information will be sent or from which it will be retrieved and the routes by which that information will be sent and received. And this is very often accomplished using DNS configurations.[22]

This is significantly more true today than it was at the time of the DC Circuit’s review of the 2015 Open Internet Order, and even more so true than it was at the time of the Brand X case. The highly technical nature of the Internet, including the features provided by some, but not all, ISPs, has changed dramatically since the 2015 Open Internet Order—and it continues to change. Some ISPs are working to deploy technologies like the Internet Engineering Task Force’s proposed Non-Queue-Building Per-Hop Behavior standard to improve DNS performance.[23] Some ISPs are working to support development of new active queue management technologies, such as the Internet Engineering Task Force’s proposed Low Latency, Low Loss, Scalable Throughput standard, which, again, have the potential to dramatically improve performance of Internet services.[24] Larger ISPs can implement dynamic routing across their networks to improve performance.[25] These are all service that some, but not all, ISPs are likely to implement to offer than enhance users’ ability to acquire, retrieve, use, or make available information—and in their improved forms none is necessary to the management or operation of the underlying telecommunications service.

Similarly, the necessity of DNS services provided by ISPs has only decreased in recent years. Today there are several free, open DNS services, including services provided by Google and Cloudflare. Statistics suggest that at least 20% of Internet users use these services instead of DNS services provided by their ISP.[26] There are parts of the world in which such services account for more than 50% of the market, demonstrating the extent to which such services are not necessary to the management or operation of the underlying telecommunications system.[27] Private VPN services are widely advertised and obviate the need for an ISP’s DNS services. Web browsers such as Chrome and Firefox include support for DNS over HTTPS, including their own DNS server settings—indeed, by default Firefox bypasses the ISPs’ DNS servers entirely.[28]

Together, these demonstrate the extent to which even a mundane-seeming service like DNS is more than a mere network management feature. While Justice Scalia’s argument in Brand X that DNS is not an information service might have been reasonable at the time, with each passing year that argument becomes weaker. Today, DNS is a standalone service, undergoing active research and development, offered in a competitive marketplace. Consumers can, and do, bypass their ISPs’ DNS services; standalone products like web browsers and VPN services can, and do, bypass their users’ ISPs. And ISPs invest in improving the quality of their own DNS services not because it improves their management of the service—marginal increases in DNS performance offer zero benefit to the management, control, or operation of a telecommunications system—but because it enhances the users’ ability to generate, acquire, store, transform, process, retrieve, utilize, or make available information via telecommunications.

II. Ongoing Development of the Broadband Industry, Notably Including Congressional Broadband Programs, Cast Doubt on the Proposed Rules

The NPRM expresses concern that ISPs “have the incentive and ability to engage in practices that pose a threat to Internet openness” and seeks comment on the state of competition in the market.[29] Contrary to the NPRM’s concerns, the state of competition in the BIAS market is robust and continues to increase. While the NPRM cites to 2021 data that that approximately 36 percent of households do not have access to two or more providers offering 100/20 Mbps wireline Internet service, that same data shows that more than 86 percent of households do have competitive options at the 25/3 Mbps level—even where a customer may only have a single ISP offering 100/20 Mbps speeds, almost all of those customers have at least one other option that creates competitive pressure.[30]

But the NPRM’s cited data is subject to greater criticism on other fronts. First, it cites to service availability data from 2021—a period during which ISPs were rapidly expanding their capacity to accommodate pandemic-era demands. The rate of this expansion was supplement by tens of billions of dollars of funding was made available through the American Rescue Plan Act (ARPA) to support broadband infrastructure investment, none of which is included in the cited data.[31] This data also doesn’t consider satellite options—Space X’s Starlink is now widely available throughout the United States[32] and Amazon’s Kupier project is beginning to put satellites into orbit.[33] And it excludes consideration of fixed wireless services, including both those commonly offered by WISPs and new 5G fixed wireless services offered by traditional wireless companies like T-Mobile and Verizon. The exclusion of fixed wireless services is notable given the pace at which consumers are embracing the technology as an alternative to traditional wireline service options.[34]

And, of course, the numbers cited by the NPRM exclude future broadband availability that will be facilitated by the Broadband Equity Access and Deployment (BEAD) program, which will increase broadband availability in currently un- and underserved areas.

The BEAD program draws attention to another concern about the proposed rules: over the past several years Congress has enacted numerous laws that support broadband investment but has not included net neutrality or open internet considerations in any of them. As will be discussed in the final section of these comments, the ultimate question for any federal agency action is whether it is authorized by Congress. The concept of net neutrality has been debated in Congress for more than a decade—it not conceivable that Congress was not aware of concerns such as those animating this NPRM as it developed the BEAD program. An inference can therefore be drawn from the fact that Congress, in allocating tens of billions of dollars in support for broadband investment, did not think it necessary to include provisions relating to network neutrality, even though doing so would settle a debate that has spanned four presidential administrations and produced substantial uncertainty within industry.

Indeed, a related inference might be drawn from Congress’s decision to entrust the National Telecommunications and Infrastructure Agency to oversee the BEAD program’s more-than $42 billion budget.[35] The BEAD program has many similarities to the Commission’s longstanding universal service programs, including raising many issues about which one would ordinarily assume the Commission as—and is viewed by Congress as having—substantial expertise. That Congress turned to another agency for the implementation of the largest broadband infrastructure program in the nation’s history should provide guidance on how broadly to interpret the Commission’s authority under the Communications Act to implement related program such as those proposed in the NPRM.[36]

III. First Amendment Considerations Cast Doubt on the Proposed Rules

The proposed rules raise at least three sets of concerns under the First Amendment. First, whether imposition of common carriage obligations is problematic under First Amendment principles. Second, whether the specific proposed rules are problematic under First Amendment principles, even absent reclassification. And third, the relevance of cases currently pending before the Supreme Court to the proposed rules.

The last of these concerns can be addressed with brevity: NetChoice v. Paxton is currently pending before the Supreme Court, with an opinion expected this term.[37] This case asks the Court to consider whether laws that limit social media platforms’ content-moderation practices, imposing common-carriage-like obligations upon them, comply with the First Amendment. The laws that the Court is reviewing bear similarity to the rules proposed by the Commission and there is a high likelihood that the Court’s decision with have significant bearing on these proposed rules. It would be imprudent to adopt any rules on this topic until the Supreme Court issues its opinion in NetChoice.

The NetChoice case also illustrates the next point to consider: whether imposition of common carriage obligations is problematic under the First Amendment. There is a long history of efforts to impose such obligations on communications platforms, from the social media at issue in NetChoice, to radio and television broadcasters, news papers, cable networks, and telephone networks.[38] But it turns out that the idea of “imposing common carriage obligations” gets the question backwards. The most universally accepted definition of common carriage turns on whether the firm eschews exercising editorial discretion over the content it carries and instead holds itself out as serving all members of the public without engaging in individualized bargaining.[39] In other words, the question is not whether government can impose common carriage obligations—it is whether a firm conducts its business in the style of a common carrier. Doing so can create an obligation to honor the obligations of common carriage (which may come with regulatory benefits). But a firm can avoid those obligations by engaging in individualized bargaining. This criterion constitutes the central consideration in all leading discussions of common carriage.[40]

This leads to the curious conclusion that the Commission’s proposal to classify BIAS as a Title II telecommunications service—a common carriage service—would only have effect to the extent that a BIAS provider elects to hold itself out as offering a common carriage service. This conclusion is reflected in the exchange that took place during the D.C. Circuit’s decision not to rehear the decision upholding the 2015 Open Internet Order en banc. When then-Judge Kavanaugh objected that classifying ISPs as common carriers impermissibly abridged their editorial discretion,[41] the authors of the majority opinion countered, explaining that “[w]hen a broadband provider holds itself out as giving customers neutral, indiscriminate access to web content of their own choosing, the First Amendment poses no obstacle to holding the provider to its representation.”[42] The 2015 Open Internet Order did not implicate the First Amendment because it only purported to regulate services over which providers exercised no editorial discretion.[43] This discussion implicitly recognized that speech over which providers exercise editorial control is protected by the First Amendment. If that were not the case, the fact that the 2015 Open Internet Order affected only speech over which providers exercised no editorial discretion would have been completely unresponsive to the concerns raised by then-Judge Kavanaugh. As described by the majority, this is a “if you say it, do it” theory, nothing more.[44]

Indeed, the initial Circuit Court opinion reached a similar conclusion—and noted the 2015 Open Internet Order recognized as much as well:

If a broadband provider nonetheless were to choose to exercise editorial discretion—for instance, by picking a limited set of websites to carry and offering that service as a curated internet experience—it might then qualify as a First Amendment speaker. But the Order itself excludes such providers from the rules. . . . Providers that may opt to exercise editorial discretion—for instance, by offering access only to a limited segment of websites specifically catered to certain content—would not offer a standardized service that can reach “substantially all” endpoints. The rules therefore would not apply to such providers, as the FCC has affirmed.[45]

The perverse incentive this creates bears emphasis. It is clear from the history of the Commission’s Open Internet proceedings that BIAS providers do not want to be subject to Title II regulation. These providers might today hold themselves out as providing services that might be considered by consumers to be common carriage services. If these providers want to avoid the obligations of Title II regulation, they would be able to do so by reducing the scope of their services to the point that they cannot be seen as holding themselves out as common carriers. The First Amendment affords no path for the Commission to compel ISPs to do otherwise.

A question still remains whether the specific rules proposed in the NPRM are problematic under First Amendment principles, even absent reclassification. In Turner, the Supreme Court upheld “must-carry” rules for cable networks, which are not common carriers, even where those networks have some claim to editorial discretion.[46] The result in Turner, however, turned on the “gatekeeper” or “bottleneck” control resulting from “the fact that there could only be one cable connection to any home” that places the cable operator in a position to block any other content providers from gaining access to subscribers.[47] In so holding, the Court emphasized the physical (rather than economic) nature of this consideration by contrasting cable with newspapers, which, “no matter how secure its local monopoly, does not possess the power to obstruct readers’ access to other competing publications.”[48] In an era of multimodal communications, where households routinely have connections to telephone, cable, and fiber optic networks, as well is fixed wireless, mobile wireless, and satellite connectivity options, makes clear the inapplicability of this rationale to platforms that lack control over an exclusive physical connection precludes applying this rationale to ISPs.

IV. The Major Questions Doctrine Casts Doubt on the Proposed Rules

The NPRM asks dozens of questions over several paragraphs relating to the Major Questions Doctrine.[49] First formally recognized by the Supreme Court in 2022, this doctrine explains that the Court “expect[s] Congress to speak clearly if it wishes to assign to an agency decisions of vast ‘economic and political significance.’”[50] Although only first recognized by the Court in 2022, the Major Questions Doctrine has developed over a span of many decades, through both Supreme Court cases and those decided by lower courts.[51] Importantly, nothing in these cases suggests that an agency’s recognition that its decisions may raise major questions renders those decisions any less major. Rather, the fact that an agency feels it is necessary to ask whether its decisions raise major questions suggests that those questions may well be major. This alone should give the agency pause about taking such decisions—especially in an era of intense judicial scrutiny of agency action it would a curious decision for any agency instead seek to structure its decisions so as to avoid the appearance of their having vast economic or political significance.

The vast significance of the proposed rules cannot be overstated—though the NPRM seems notably to attempt to understate it. Discussing broadband in 2015, former Chair Tom Wheeler described the Internet as “the most powerful network in the history of mankind.”[52] This was echoed in the 2015 Open Internet Order. The first sentence of the 2015 Order asserted that “[t]he open Internet drives the American economy and serves, every day, as a critical tool for America’s citizens to conduct commerce, communicate, educate, entertain, and engage in the world around them.”[53] Similarly, the NPRM for that Order began with: “The Internet is America’s most important platform for economic growth, innovation, competition, [ and] free expression . . . . [It] has been, and remains to date, the preeminent 21st century engine for innovation and the economic and social benefits that follow.”[54]

And, as made clear in the current NPRM, this importance has only been amplified since the beginning of the COVID-19 pandemic: “In the time since the RIF Order, propelled by the COVID-19 pandemic, BIAS has become even more essential to consumers for work, health, education, community, and everyday life.”[55] As stated by Chair Rosenworcel, “broadband is no longer nice-to-have; it’s need-to-have for everyone, everywhere. Broadband is an essential service”[56] Commissioner Starks similarly states that “there is simply no way to overstate broadband’s impact on the lives of individual Americans.”[57] And Commissioner Gomez states “El acceso a internet de banda ancha no solo es una herramienta vital para la educación, la atención de salud y para comunicarnos con nuestros seres queridos. También es un conducto de crítica importancia, esencial para la vida moderna.”[58]

In the NPRM, the Commission points to the D.C. Circuit’s opinion in the previous Open Internet Order case, as well as to Brand X itself, to suggest that the Brand X opinion settles the question of whether the Commission has authority to adopt these rules.[59] As an initial matter, that question simply was not before the Court in Brand X. In Brand X, the Court considered only whether the FCC could decide the classification under the Chevron after a lower court had adopted a conflicting interpretation of an ambiguous statute.[60] The question of whether Commission had authority to regulate cable broadband Internet service as a Title II telecommunications service was not a contested issue—only whether it could instead interpret ambiguity in the Communications Act to instead regulate it as a Title I information service. Similarly, the Major Questions Doctrine had not been expressly recognized by the Supreme Court at the time of the D.C. Circuit’s 2016 opinion. While it was “in the air,” it was a controversial doctrine—one that the Supreme Court had yet to expressly embrace. But the Court has done so now.

In the D.C. Circuit’s denial of en banc review, the judges Srinivasan and Tatel (the authors of the majority opinion under review) offers a more fulsome consideration of the major questions issue[61]—prompted by the dissenting opinion of then-judge Kavanaugh.[62] But in light of the Supreme Court’s own more fulsome embrace of the doctrine since that opinion, this analysis is unconvincing. In addition to over-relying on Brand X as having decided the matter, the majority makes another conceptually uncertain assumption: even if the Commission could have regulated Internet services at the time of Brand X, that doesn’t necessarily mean that the Commission has such authority today. The economic and political significance of those services is vastly different today than it was then. The Commission disclaimed such authority for more than 15 years, during which time the social, economic, technical, and political understandings of the Internet changed fundamentally from what they were at the time of Brand X. As discussed in the following paragraphs, this consideration is relevant to the Major Questions Doctrine analysis but goes unrecognized by the D.C. Circuit opinion.

While Brand X does not support the contention that classifying BIAS as a Title II does not present major question, it does briefly draw attention to an important argument that it does present a major question: respondents in Brand X raised the concern that “the Commission’s construction [of cable Internet as a Title I information service] is unreasonable because it allows any communications provider to ‘evade’ common-carrier regulation by the expedient of bundling information service with telecommunications.”[63] The Court rejected the premise of this argument, so did not decide whether it would, in fact, be an unreasonable construction.[64] But the same issue runs through the proposed rules: that BIAS providers need not hold out their offerings as common carriage services, so could “evade” Title II regulation through a simple expedient. Unlike in Brand X, where the Court rejected the premise that such evasion was possible, here the D.C. Circuit has found that the First Amendment compels such a result and the Commission has conceded that the rules necessarily allow it.[65]

This is a facially absurd result that demonstrates the fundamental mismatch between Title II regulation at BIAS service. Title II is a pervasive regulatory regime designed to regulate one of the foundational, utility-style, natural monopoly, industries of the 20th century. It was designed for a technology to which editorial discretion was largely viewed as inapplicable.[66] And it was part of a regulatory quid pro quo that gave telephone carriers a privileged regulatory position in exchange for offering service on a common-carriage basis. As we approached the 21st century, Title II was substantially amended through the 1996 Telecommunications Act to be a pervasively deregulatory statute that would phase out regulate in favor of competition and did so largely in response to the development of networks that offered advanced communications capabilities that were increasingly removed from the transparent, point-to-point, communications model of the 20th century telephone network.[67]

It is little surprise that the Commission’s efforts today to reregulate modern communications networks under an expressly deregulatory act runs into problems such as the possibility for evasion. Similarly, it is unsurprising that it required tailoring of the Title II regulatory regime through extensive use of forbearance—another hallmark of a regulatory decision that presents major questions.[68]

The idea that Congress intends the Commission to be the primary regulator for BIAS services faces even greater headwind following the pandemic. Congress—which has longstanding awareness of the net neutrality debates—put in place significant communications-related regulations with the IIJA. This included the BEAD program, the Affordable Connectivity Program, and laying the groundwork for the Commission’s recently proposed Digital Discrimination rules.[69] This legislation, adopted during a period of single-party control of Congress and the White House, could have easily clarified the Commission’s regulatory authority over BIAS. Instead, it assigned primary authority for the federal government’s flagship broadband infrastructure program to another agency and assigned to the Commission new authority to adopt more limited broadband discrimination rules to ensure equitable access to that infrastructure.

These circumstances bear resemblance to the circumstances discussed by the Court in FDA v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp, one of the precursor cases to the Major Questions Doctrine.[70] In Brown & Williamson, the Court held that the FDA did not have authority to regulate tobacco, a drug, under its statutory authority to regulate drugs. In reaching this conclusion, the Court recognized among other things that Congress knew the FDA did not have a clear claim to regulate tobacco and had adopted alternative regulatory regimes relating to the regulation of tobacco without giving the FDA regulatory authority over the matter.[71] It also recognized that “it is hardly conceivable that Congress—and in this setting, any Member of Congress—was not abundantly aware of what was going on.”[72] Here, as there, if Congress intended the FCC to exercise the vast authority that the Commission would claim in the NPRM, Congress was aware of the uncertainty over the Commission’s authority and could readily have clarified the matter.

Conclusion

The defining feature of the Safeguarding and Securing the Open Internet NPRM is its proposed reclassification of BIAS as a Title II telecommunication service. By choosing this approach, the Commission is needlessly steering into both legal uncertainty and political controversy. Reclassification will be challenged in court; these challenges have a high likelihood of success and, in the best case, will yield years of uncertainty for industry, consumers, and the Commission. Indeed, cases currently pending before the Supreme Court could force reconsideration of the NPRM before the proposed rules could even be finalized.

This is a curious approach to take, given that ISPs can, in effect, “opt out” of reclassification by offering an Internet experience that does not purport to be a common carriage service. This would be an unfortunate outcome that would lead to consumer confusion and possibly to degraded user experiences. It is a perverse approach to regulation, imposing burdensome rules that can be avoided by degrading the quality of service offered to consumers. And this demonstrates the extent to which the proposed reclassification is a perversion of the purposes of Title II—and to which it therefore is a decision that raises major questions.

And the approach is all the more curious given that there is little demonstrable need for the rules in the first place. But if the rules are to be adopted, the Commission could do so without reclassification. Were the Commission to follow the roadmap offered by the D.C. Circuit in Verizon, it is entirely likely that industry would acquiesce to the rules. That is the path the Commission should take, if it is to go down this path at all.

[1]    Safeguarding and Securing the Open Internet, WC Docket No. 23-230, Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, 88 Fed. Reg. 76,048 (Nov. 3, 2023) (NPRM).

[2]    Further detail on many of the topics discussed in these comments can be found in our prior publications. See, e.g., [[past comments, briefs, articles]].

[3]    Consolidated Appropriations Act, 2021, Pub. L. No. 116-260, § 904 (2020).

[4]    American Rescue Plan Act of 2021, Pub. L. No. 117-2, § 7402 (2021) (ARPA).

[5]    Infrastructure Investment and Jobs Act, Pub. L. No. 117-58, § 60502 (2021) (IIJA)

[6]    Id. § 60101, et seq.

[7]    Id. § 60102.

[8]    See Tom Wheeler, Finding the Best Path Forward to Protect the Open Internet (April 29, 2014), available at https://www.fcc.gov/news-events/blog/2014/04/29/finding-best-path-forward-protect-open-internet (“In its Verizon v. FCC decision the D.C. Circuit laid out a blueprint for how the FCC could use Section 706 of the Telecommunications Act of 1996 to create Open Internet rules that would stick. I have repeatedly stated that I viewed the court’s ruling as an invitation that I intended to accept.”).

[9]    See Part IV.

[10]   Nat’l Cable & Telecomms. Ass’n v. Brand X, 545 U.S. 967 (2005) (Brand X).

[11]   See Part I.

[12]   See Part III.

[13]   Brand X at 989 (“Cable companies in the broadband Internet service business ‘offer’ consumers an information service in the form of Internet access and they do so “via telecommunications.”).

[14]   Id. At 990 (“The question, then, is whether the transmission component of cable modem service is sufficiently integrated with the finished service to make it reasonable to describe the two as a single, integrated offering”). More precisely, the Court was considering whether this interpretation, made by the FCC, can be sustained under the Chevron doctrine. Id. at 989 (“This construction passes Chevron’s first step.”); id. at 997 (“We also conclude that the Commission’s construction was ‘a reasonable policy choice for the Commission to make’ at Chevron’s second step.”).

[15]   NPRM, paras. 11, 75–77 (citing U.S.Telecom Ass’n v. FCC, 825 F.3d 674(D.C. Cir. 2016) (USTA))

[16]   USTA at 705.

[17]   Id. at 766, n.8 (Williams, J, dissenting).

[18]   Id. at 748.

[19]   Brand X at 991.

[20]   Id. at 1012–13 (Scalia, J, dissenting).

[21]   Id. at 999, n.3.

[22]   See Reply Comments of Christopher S. Yoo, WC Docket No. 17-108.

[23]   A Non-Queue-Building Per-Hop Behavior (NQB PHB) for Differentiated Services, IETF Transport Area Working Group Draft (Oct. 24, 2022), available at https://www.ietf.org/archive/id/draft-ietf-tsvwg-nqb-14.html.

[24]   Low Latency, Low Loss, Scalable Throughput (L4S) Internet Service: Architecture, IETF Transport Area Working Group Draft  (July 27, 2022), available at https://www.ietf.org/archive/id/draft-ietf-tsvwg-l4s-arch-19.html. See also Mitchell Clark, The Quiet Plan to Make the Internet Feel Faster, The Verge (Dec. 9, 2023).

[25]   See, e.g., Joan Feigenbaum et al, A BGP-based Mechanism for Lowest-Cost Routing, 18 Distributed Computing 61 (2005).

[26]   Geoff Huston, Looking at Centrality in the DNS,APNIC Blog (Nov. 22, 2022), available at  https://blog.apnic.net/2022/11/22/looking-at-centrality-in-the-dns/ (“the use of ISP-provided recursive resolution occurs for between 65% to 80% of users . . . known open resolvers have a 20% market share”).

[27]   Id.

[28]   Firefox DNS-over-HTTPS, Mozilla Support, available at https://support.mozilla.org/en-US/kb/firefox-dns-over-https (“When DoH is enabled, Firefox by default directs DoH queries to DNS servers that are operated by a trusted partner . . . .”) (visited Dec. 13, 2023).

[29]   NPRM, paras 126, 128.

[30]   Importantly, and contrary to the longstanding policy approach of defining performance metrics that focus on increasingly higher bandwidth (Mbps targets), “It has been demonstrated that, once access network bit rates reach levels now common in the developed world, increasing link capacity offers diminishing returns if latency (delay) is not addressed.” Low Latency, Low Loss, Scalable Throughput (L4S) Internet Service: Architecture, supra note 24. Implementation of new technologies, such as L4S, could increase competition between existing networks than at lower cost than building out entirely new, increasingly higher-speed, infrastructure.

[31]   See Anna Read & Kelly Wert, How States Are Using Pandemic Relief Funds to Boost Broadband Access, Pew (Dec. 6, 2021), available at https://www.pewtrusts.org/en/research-and-analysis/articles/2021/12/06/how-states-are-using-pandemic-relief-funds-to-boost-broadband-access.

[32]   Starlink Availability Map, available at https://www.starlink.com/map.

[33]   See Joey Roulette, Amazon’s Prototype Kuiper Satellites Operating Successfully, Reuters (Nov. 16, 2023), available at https://www.reuters.com/technology/amazons-prototype-kuiper-satellites-operate-successfully-2023-11-16/.

[34]   See Mike Dano, T-Mobile Exceeds in Q3, Talks Broadband Strategy, Light Reading (Oct. 25, 2023), available at https://www.lightreading.com/fixed-wireless-access/t-mobile-exceeds-in-q3-talks-broadband-strategy (“T-Mobile reported a total of 557,000 new fixed wireless access (FWA) customers, a figure above most analyst expectations and slightly ahead of the company’s recent quarterly pace.”); Mike Dano, FWA Captures 90% of All New US Customers, Pleasing Around 90% of Them, Light Reading (March 6, 2023), available at https://www.lightreading.com/fixed-wireless-access/fwa-captures-90-of-all-new-us-customers-pleasing-around-90-of-them (“fixed wireless services accounted for 90% of all net broadband customer additions in the US during 2022 . . . . 90% rated their service as ‘good enough.’”).

[35]   IIJA § 60502(b)(2).

[36]   See infra, Part IV.

[37]   Moody v. NetChoice, LLC; NetChoice, LLC v. Moody; NetChoice, LLC v. Paxton, Nos. 22-277, 22-393 and 22-555 (U.S. Sup. Ct.).

[38]   See generally Christopher Yoo, Free Speech and the Myth of the Internet as an Unintermediated Experience, 78 Geo. Wash. L. rev. 697, Part II (2010) (surveying regulation of various media technologies).

[39]   See Biden v. Knight First Amendment Inst., 141 S. Ct. 1220, 1222 (2021) (Thomas, J., concurring).

[40]   See FCC v. Midwest Video Corp., 440 U.S. 689, 701 (1979); U.S. Telecom Ass’n v. FCC, 825 F.3d 674, 740 (D.C. Cir. 2016); Verizon v. FCC, 740 F.3d 623, 651 (D.C. Cir. 2014); Cellco P’ship v. FCC, 700 F.3d 534, 548 (D.C. Cir. 2012); NARUC II, 533 F.2d at 608; NARUC I, 525 F.2d at 641. Congress, courts, and agencies have applied the same formulation in a wide variety of contexts. See 15 U.S.C. § 375(3); 46 U.S.C. § 40102(7)(A); 40 C.F.R. § 202.10(b); Edwards v. Pac. Fruit Express Co., 390 U.S. 538, 540 (1968); Woolsey v. Nat’l Transp. Safety Bd., 993 F.2d 516 524 n.2. (5th Cir. 1993); Flytenow, Inc. v. FAA, 808 F.3d 882, 887–88 (D.C. Cir. 2015); Nichimen Co. v. M. V. Farland, 462 F.2d 319, 326 (2d Cir. 1972); Kelly v. Gen. Elec. Co., 110 F. Supp. 4, 6 (E.D. Pa.), aff’d, 204 F.2d 692 (3d Cir. 1953).

[41]   U.S. Telecom Ass’n, 855 F.3d at 484–89 (Kavanaugh, J., dissenting from the denial of rehearing en banc)

[42]   Id. at 392 (Srinivasan, J., joined by Tatel, J., concurring in the denial of the petition for rehearing en banc).

[43]   Id. at 388–89.

[44]   Id. at 392.

[45]   USTA at 743.

[46]   Turner Broad. Sys., Inc. v. FCC (Turner I), 512 U.S. 622, 656–57 (1994).

[47]   Id. at 656.

[48]   Id.

[49]   NPRM, paras 81–84.

[50]   West Virginia v. EPA, 142 S. Ct. 2587 (2022) (quoting Utility Air Regulatory Group v. EPA, 573 U.S. 302, 324 (2014)).

[51]   Id. at 2609 (“major questions doctrine label . . . took hold because it refers to an identifiable body of law that has developed over a series of significant cases all addressing a particular and recurring problem: agencies asserting highly consequential power beyond what Congress could reasonably be understood to have granted. Scholars and jurists have recognized the common threads between those decisions. So have we.” (citing cases dating to MCI Telecommunications Corp. v. American Telephone & Telegraph Co., 512 U.S. 218 (1994) (MCI)).

[52]   See Remarks of FCC Chairman Tom Wheeler, Silicon Flatirons Center (Feb. 9, 2015), available at http://transition.fcc.gov/Daily_Releases/Daily_Business/2015/db0209/DOC-331943A1.pdf; see also of same, available at https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=vHsHkKpxVkQ (in which Chairman Wheeler was more emphatic than in his prepared remarks); Brian Fung, FCC chairman warns: The GOP’s net neutrality bill could jeopardize broadband’s ‘vast future’, Washington Post (Jan. 29, 2015), available at http://www.washingtonpost.com/blogs/the-switch/wp/2015/01/29/fcc-chairman-warns-that-republican-bill-couldjeopardize-broadbands-vast-future/.

[53]   Protecting and Promoting the Open Internet, GN Docket No. 14-28, Report and Order on Remand, Declaratory Ruling, and Order, 80 Fed. Red. 19,737 (Apr. 15, 2015).

[54]   Protecting and Promoting the Open Internet, GN Docket No. 14-28, Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, 79 Fed. Reg. 37,448 (July 1, 2014).

[55]   NPRM, para 16.

[56]   NPRM, Statement of Chairwoman Jessica Rosenworcel.

[57]   NPRM, Statement of Commissioner Geoffrey Starks.

[58]   NPRM, Statement of Commissioner Anna M. Gomez.

[59]   NPRM, para 81 (“In the USTA decision, the D.C. Circuit reasoned that Brand X conclusively held that the Commission has the authority to determine the proper statutory classification of BIAS and that its determinations are entitled to deference, and so there is no need to consult the major questions doctrine here.”).

[60]   Brand X, at 974 (“We must decide whether [the FCC’s] conclusion [that cable companies that sell broadband Internet service do not provide ‘telecommunications service’ as the Communications Act defines that term] is a lawful construction of the Communications Act under Chevron U. S. A. Inc. v. Natural Resources Defense Council, Inc. and the Administrative Procedure Act. We hold that it is.”).

[61]   U.S. Telecom Ass’n, 855 F.3d at 385–88.

[62]   U.S. Telecom Ass’n, 855 F.3d at 422–26 (Kavanaugh, J., dissenting).

[63]   Brand X, at 997.

[64]   Id. (“We need not decide whether a construction that resulted in these consequences would be unreasonable because we do not believe that these results follow from the construction the Commission adopted.”).

[65]   See supra, Part III.

[66]   But see Christopher Yoo, Free Speech and the Myth of the Internet as an Unintermediated Experience, 78 Geo. Wash. L. rev. 697, 752–57 (2010) (discussing cases starting in the 1980s that began to recognize the applicability of editorial discretion concepts to telephone carriers).

[67]   See Telecommunications Act of 1996, Pub. L. No. 104-104 (1996) (“An act to promote competition and reduce regulation in order to secure lower prices and higher quality services for American telecommunications consumers and encourage the rapid deployment of new telecommunications technologies.”).

[68]   See U.S. Telecom Ass’n, 855 F.3d at 404–09 (Brown, J., dissenting from the denial of rehearing en banc) (citing MCI and Utility Air Regulatory Group v. EPA in discussing the problematic use of the Commission’s forbearance authority to “tailor” Title II to fit the needs of BIAS regulation).

[69]   See supra, notes 3–5.

[70]   FDA v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 529 U.S. 120 (2000).

[71]   Id. at 155-156.

[72]   Id. at 156.

Continue reading
Telecommunications & Regulated Utilities

ICLE Comments to FCC on Title II NPRM

Regulatory Comments I.        Introduction Writing on behalf of the International Center for Law & Economics (ICLE), we thank the Federal Communications Commission (“FCC” or “the Commission”) for . . .

I.        Introduction

Writing on behalf of the International Center for Law & Economics (ICLE), we thank the Federal Communications Commission (“FCC” or “the Commission”) for the opportunity to respond to this notice of proposed rulemaking (“NPRM”) as the Commission seeks, yet again, to reclassify broadband internet-access services under Title II of the Communications Act of 1934.

The new NPRM emphasizes the principles of an “open internet,” but falls short of providing a concrete operational definition of what this entails.[1] The Commission’s vague and open-ended description of a “open internet” introduces enormous ambiguities that could grant the FCC unwarranted and expanded scope of discretion. In suggesting that openness equates to basic consumer access, without clear limitations or exceptions, the order leaves room for interpretation of what constitutes “open” access. This not only hampers stakeholders from understanding the boundaries of compliance, but also gives the FCC an opaque veil of authority that could be applied both expansively and inconsistently.

Some critics see the FCC’s pursuit of common-carrier regulation of broadband internet as an attempt to “control” an industry with vast economic and political significance.[2] That may be true. As we discuss in Section II, a more charitable criticism is that the Commission mistakenly believes that the provision of broadband internet is a natural monopoly that is best served by utility-style regulation. Alternatively, it could be argued that the FCC mistakenly believes that a dynamic and competitive industry marked by rapid innovation, improving quality, and falling prices can be effectively regulated as if it were a public utility. Under any of these rationales, Title II regulation is mistaken at best, and nefarious at worst.

Although much has changed since the 2015 Order,[3] nothing has happened that newly justifies the Commission reimposing Title II on broadband service. Perhaps recognizing the difficulty this poses, the Commission offers several new justifications for Title II regulation. In particular, “national security” is offered as a primary justification. In the 2015 Order, “net neutrality” was mentioned nearly 70 times. In contrast, the recent NPRM uses the term only a handful of times: once in the text and the others in only two footnotes. The 2015 Order mentioned “national security” only three times, while the NPRM uses the term more than five dozen times.

In addition, the FCC’s NPRM provides several other new justifications for sweeping regulation of broadband-internet access:

  • COVID-19: “[T]he COVID-19 pandemic and the rapid shift of work, education, and health care online demonstrated how essential broadband Internet connections are for consumers’ participation in our society and economy.”[4]
  • Federal spending on provider investments and consumer subsidies: “Congress responded by investing tens of billions of dollars into building out broadband Internet networks and making access more affordable and equitable, culminating in the generational investment of $65 billion in the Infrastructure Investment and Jobs Act.”[5]
  • The need for a uniform national regulatory system: “[T]his authority will allow the Commission to protect consumers, including by issuing straightforward, clear rules to prevent Internet service providers from engaging in practices harmful to consumers, competition, and public safety, and by establishing a uniform, national regulatory approach rather than disparate requirements that vary state-by-state.”[6]

We caution the Commission to take care when relying on these justifications, for several reasons. First, the COVID-19 justification is at odds with the way history unfolded. U.S. broadband providers’ responses to the steep increase in demand during the pandemic was a demonstrable success of broadband competition (especially compared to how networks abroad fared).[7]

The Commission’s reliance on the passage of the Infrastructure Investment and Jobs Act (IIJA) is also a problematic justification for Title II regulation. The legislative process would have been a perfect time for Congress to legislate net neutrality or Title II regulation as it was debating the investment of tens of billions of dollars to encourage broadband buildout for the next decade or so. But no such provisions were included in the spending bills. If anything, this should indicate that the Commission should refrain from such an excessive regulatory intervention.

Even the Commission’s newly enacted digital-discrimination rules undermine the case for Title II regulation. Congress included a very terse statement that the Commission should look into impermissible discrimination in broadband deployment, but gave zero indication that it wanted Title II reclassification to serve as a remedy, even if such discrimination was found.[8] In short, if Congress intended to regulate broadband internet under Title II, it had numerous opportunities to do so in the recent past, but chose otherwise.

When it comes to national security, Congress has created a number of entities that have oversight powers.[9] But despite recent legislative investment in broadband deployment, Congress gave no indication that it wished the FCC to become a body driven by a national-security mission.  Thus, the Commission’s attempt to step into this arena appears both redundant and outside its core competencies. This further suggests that imposing net neutrality under the guise of such justifications might be unfounded, rather than grounded in a changed internet landscape or emergent security threats.

Aside from these overarching concerns advising against Title II regulation, the following comments seek to evaluate the FCC’s numerous beliefs and conclusions, as well as answer questions posed by the NPRM.

In Section II, we report that, by most measures, U.S. broadband competition is vibrant and has improved dramatically since the COVID-19 pandemic. We show that, since 2021, more households are connected to the internet, broadband speeds have increased while prices have declined, more households are served by more than a single provider, and new technologies—such as satellite and 5G—have increased internet access and intermodal competition among providers.

In that section, we also conclude that a mere “incentive and ability” of providers to engage in practices that pose a threat to “internet openness” (however defined) is insufficient justification to impose outright bans on certain practices that have been demonstrated to enhance internet performance, foster investment, and improve consumer and edge provider well-being. Moreover, robust and increasing broadband competition would place a substantial check on the “incentive and ability” for provider attempts to engage in anticompetitive or harmful conduct.

Rather than promoting “openness,” Title II may serve to suppress it, as it would ban or regulate both existing practices or future innovative practices that simultaneously boost provider returns and improve internet users’ experience. As such, Section II argues that the heavy-handed regulation proposed by the NPRM is likely to both reduce investment returns and increase the uncertainty of those returns. This would thereby stifle future broadband investment, especially among small and rural providers.

As discussed in Section II.C.2, paid prioritization has been demonstrated to benefit consumers and edge providers and, in some, cases may be necessary to deliver some high-demand internet services. We also present evidence that throttling of application-service providers is virtually nonexistent and that consumers are largely indifferent to throttling policies as currently practiced. While the NPRM does not anticipate regulating data caps or usage-based pricing, we argue that there is a significant likelihood these practices could be scrutinized under the proposed “internet conduct” rules. Both practices have been shown to be especially beneficial to low-income or low-usage internet subscribers.

Section III describes how already-existing laws and agencies are well-equipped to deal with competition, consumer protection, and national-security issues. Many of the issues the FCC uses to justify extending its purview do not require Title II reclassification, or even action from the FCC itself.

Lastly, in Section IV, we demonstrate that the FCC’s proposed rules will certainly invite challenge under the “major questions doctrine,” which requires a clear grant of authority from Congress when an agency action exercises powers of vast economic and political significance. Moreover, based on recent Supreme Court precedent, there is a significant likelihood that the Commission’s proposed Title II regulation will be struck down by the courts. Reclassification of broadband as a Title II telecommunications service would clearly be an exercise of powers of “vast economic and political significance.” Broadband providers have invested billions of dollars per year into building out reliable high-speed networks throughout the country, serving hundreds of millions of consumers.[10] Nearly every U.S. resident, business, public agency, and other organization uses broadband internet over large portions of the day. Both federal and state governments have supported this continued buildout through subsidies to providers and consumers. As then-Judge Brett Kavanaugh put it when considering the 2015 Order, the “FCC’s net neutrality rule is a major rule for the purposes of The Supreme Court’s major rules doctrine. Indeed, I believe that proposition is indisputable.”[11] It is also clear the classification of broadband under the Communications Act is ambiguous, as every court to review the question has found it to be so.[12]

II.      Title II Is Inappropriate to Regulate Broadband

The Commission’s NPRM proposes regulating broadband as a Title II telecommunications service. But such regulations are unnecessary to protect the public and will harm investment, competition, and innovation. Part II.A details the absence of evidence that would justify reclassifying broadband as a common carrier under Title II. Part II.B shows how the current “light-touch” regulatory approach under Title I promotes innovation and competition. Part II.C presents evidence that Title II reclassification will reduce investment, and Part II.D explains how the NPRM’s proposed rules will reduce innovation by broadband providers.

A.      No Adequate Justification to Change Regulatory Classification of Broadband Providers

The NPRM argues that the Commission must restore Title II authority to “safeguard the open Internet” by “clear rules to prevent Internet service providers from engaging in practices harmful to consumers, competition, and public safety….”[13] But the NPRM’s arguments to support this assertion are weak, and the evidence is sparse.

Part II.A.1 argues that the alleged harms to openness are based on poor economic logic and lack any evidence demonstrating that broadband providers have reduced “openness” in the absence of Title II regulation. Part II.A.2 examines the logic of regulating broadband as a monopoly utility, and finds it wanting in light of competitive conditions in the market. Part II.A.3 furthers that argument by detailing the level of competition in the market for high-speed internet, noting the growth in the number of providers, the falling prices and increasing speeds made available, and the increased level of intermodal competition since repeal of the 2015 Order.

1.        NPRM has not sufficiently supported its assertion of a threat to openness

In the NPRM, the Commission notes that:

We believe that the rules we propose today will establish a baseline that the Commission can use to prevent and address conduct that harms consumers and competition when it occurs. Above, we express our belief that consumers perceive and use BIAS as an essential service, critical to accessing healthcare, education, work, commerce, and civic engagement. Because of its importance, we further believe it is paramount that consumers be able to use their BIAS connections without degradation due to blocking, throttling, paid prioritization, or other harmful conduct.[14]

Relatedly, the Commission roots its proposed rules in the so-called “incentive and ability [of ISPs] to engage in practices that pose a threat to Internet openness.”[15]

But the NPRM’s proposed rules, rooted in the presumption of ISPs’ “incentive and ability” to engage in practices that threaten internet openness, rest on a speculative foundation, rather than any substantive record of violations. Given the voluminous scale of internet traffic, the evidence of actual infractions is remarkably scant. This paucity of evidence undermines the rationale for preemptive, industrywide prohibitions, which would be based on hypothetical future harms. The mere possibility of ISPs engaging in deleterious conduct does not, in itself, warrant imposing onerous rules that could impede investment in innovative business models.

The assertion that ISPs have the incentive and ability to harm open internet access lacks convincing substantiation of demonstrable harmful conduct.[16] Speculative harm cannot justify regulations that could dissuade ISPs from exploring novel and potentially pro-consumer arrangements. Where there is evidence of consumer ignorance of the tradeoffs inherent in various product offerings, the solution may lie in enhanced disclosure—providing notice and choice to consumers—not in the imposition of broad restrictions.

Furthermore, the Commission fails to distinguish between instances where so-called “paid prioritization” has pro-consumer benefits and where it may constitute an anticompetitive harm. Many business relationships that might be labeled as paid prioritization—such as Netflix’s collocation of data centers within different networks to expedite service and reduce overall network load—are unequivocally pro-consumer. Such arrangements are better understood as sensible network optimization, rather than as anticompetitive behavior.

This narrow focus on ISPs as a potential vector of consumer harm also overlooks the broader ecosystem in which content aggregators like Netflix or Google exert significant influence over access to content. These platforms can, and often do, have a more immediate effect on consumer access than do ISPs. While edge providers sometimes come under fire themselves (wrongly, in our view), it is relevant to assessing the desirability of these proposed rules whether edge providers are made more or less powerful if ISPs are constrained, and what effect that would have on consumer welfare. Relatedly, many of the concerns over blocking, throttling, and paid prioritization are, in essence, expressing a concern that these edge providers will be unable to successfully bargain with ISPs. This, however, is a strange basis for such rules, as many of these firms are as large as or larger than any particular ISP. Moreover, the power these large firms exert in business relationships with ISPs establishes conditions that have downstream benefits for all edge providers.

Thus, the NPRM’s concern over the need for “neutral” connection lanes fails to recognize that neutrality may not be the sole (or even the best) path to fostering innovation. Startups could benefit from making agreements with ISPs to ensure optimized data transmission, which could be more achievable and less costly than the NPRM suggests. Moreover, the emergence of distributed cloud computing blurs the lines between established firms and newcomers, as they often share the same infrastructure and delivery networks, muting the Commission’s concerns.

Before moving forward, the Commission should diligently investigate the likelihood of future harms absent regulation, considering that no concrete evidence has surfaced since the last two rounds of rules on this matter—or even prior—of ISPs using their alleged incentive and ability to affect consumers and edge providers detrimentally. The FCC should substantiate actual harm rather than legislate against conjectural threats. Moreover, the FCC might find that transparency rules alone, or even the mere risk of public disclosure without formal regulation, could sufficiently deter quality degradation without the need for more intrusive regulations.

2.        Widespread use of high-speed internet does not render broadband internet a public utility

The Commission concludes that broadband internet access services are “[n]ot unlike other essential utilities, such as electricity and water” and that high-speed internet “was essential or important to 90 percent of U.S. adults during the COVID-19 pandemic.”[17] The Commission appears to argue that broadband internet is therefore an essential public utility and should be regulated as such.

But many essentials to human survival—shelter, food, clothing—are thus not subject to common-carrier regulations, because they are provided by multiple suppliers in competitive markets. Utilities are considered distinct because they tend to have such significant economies of scale that (1) a single monopoly provider can provide the goods or services at a lower cost than multiple competing firms and/or (2) market demand is insufficient to support more than a single supplier.[18] Water, sewer, electricity, and natural gas are typically considered “natural” monopolies under this definition.[19] In many cases, not only are these industries treated as monopolies, but their monopoly status is codified by laws forbidding competition. At one time, local and long-distance telephone services were considered—and treated as—natural monopolies, as was cable television.[20]

Over time, innovations have eroded the “natural” monopolies in telephone and cable.[21] In 2000, 94% of U.S. households had a landline telephone, and only 42% had a mobile phone.[22] By 2018, those numbers flipped.[23] In 2015, 73% of households subscribed to cable or satellite-television service.[24] Today, fewer than half of U.S. households subscribe.[25] Much of that transition is due to the enormous improvements in broadband speed, reliability, and affordability discussed in Part II.A.3.a. Similarly, entry and intermodal competition from 5G, fixed wireless, and satellite—as discussed in Part II.A.3.c—has meant that more than 94% of the country can now access high-speed broadband from three or more providers, thereby eroding the already tenuous claims that broadband-internet service is akin to a utility.

Regulating a competitive industry as a monopoly utility is what former Justice Stephen Breyer identified as a regulatory “mismatch,” which he defined as:

[A]n area where the rationale for regulation, judged by empirical fact, is not compelling, or where there are apparently less restrictive or more incentive-based forms of governmental intervention that can obtain regulation’s purported objective. [26]

As we note throughout these comments, the federal government already has in place many laws, rules, and policies that could satisfy many of the objectives the FCC seeks with Title II reclassification. In nearly every case, existing regulations are less-restrictive, more incentive-based, or less-capricious than common-carrier regulation under Title II.

3.        Existing broadband competition renders common-carrier regulations unnecessary

The FCC seeks comment on the state of competition in broadband internet-access services.[27] The NPRM claims that more than one-third of households lack competitive choice for fixed broadband at speeds of 100/20 Mbps, and that 70% of rural households lack such choice.[28] Despite the fact that nearly one-in-eight households with at-home internet are mobile-only, the Commission concludes that fixed and mobile internet are not substitutable.[29] Against this backdrop, the FCC seeks comment regarding whether services with substantially different technologies can substitute for each other competitively, and whether consumers nationwide have an adequate choice of providers.[30]

By most measures, U.S. broadband competition is vibrant and has increased dramatically since the COVID-19 pandemic. Since 2021, more households are connected to the internet, broadband speeds have increased while prices have declined, more households are served by more than a single provider, and new technologies—such as satellite and 5G—have expanded internet access and intermodal competition among providers.

a.        More households are served by two or more providers

Criticisms of the current state of broadband deployment tend to presume it results from widespread market failure. Specifically, the critics believe that too few Americans have affordable access to adequate broadband speed and capacity and that this, in turn, is the result of insufficient competition among broadband providers.[31] For example, in her speech announcing the FCC’s latest proposal to regulate internet services under Title II, Chair Jessica Rosenworcel claimed that 80% of the country faces a monopoly or duopoly for 100 Mbps or higher download speeds.[32] But, in fact, nearly all of the country has access to at-home internet, a vast majority has access to high-speed internet, and much of the country has access to these speeds from three or more providers.

The Federal Communications Commission (FCC) defines high-speed broadband as Internet service that offers speeds of at least 25/3 Mbps.[33] The IIJA defines a location as “unserved” if it has no internet connection available or only has a connection offering speeds of less than 25/3 Mbps.[34] A location is considered “underserved” if the only options available offer speeds of less than 100/20 Mbps.[35] The third iteration of the National Broadband Map, released in November 2023, indicates:[36]

  • 8% of locations have access to connections of 25/3 Mbps or higher;
  • 5% of locations have access to speeds of 200/25 Mbps or higher.
  • Only 6.2% of locations are unserved, and 2.6% are “underserved” with connections of less than 100/20 Mbps.

The most recent FCC data on U.S. broadband deployment finds that 90% of the population in 2021 was served by one or more providers offering 250/25 Mbps or higher speeds (Table 1).[37] That is more than double the share of the population five years earlier, when only 44% of Americans had access to such speeds.[38] In 2019, the FCC did not report the share of population with access to 1,000/100 Mbps speeds or higher. In 2021, 28% of the population had access to these gigabit download speeds.

Table 1 shows that, in 2021, more than 85% of the population was covered by two or more fixed broadband providers offering 25/3 Mbps or higher speeds and more than 60% of the country was covered by three or more providers providing such speeds. If satellite and 5G providers are included, then close to 100% of the country is served by two or more high-speed providers.

Moreover, the evidence indicates that broadband competition has increased over time, as measured by the number of competing high-speed providers (Figure 1).[39]

  • 25/3 Mbps: In 2018, 73.0% of households had access to 25/3 Mbps speeds from only one or two fixed broadband providers and only 21.6% had access from three or more providers. In 2021, only 29.1% of households had access from one or two providers while 69.3% were served by three or more providers. Thus, the number of households served by three or more providers increased by 47.7 percentage points from 2018 through 2021.
  • 100/20 Mbps: In 2018, 11.6% of households had no access to 100/20 Mbps speeds and 14.8% had access from three or more fixed broadband providers. In 2021, 5.4% of households had no access, while 21.3% were served by three or more providers. Thus, the number of households served by three or more providers increased by 6.5 percentage points from 2018 through 2021.

Since the 2018 Order[40] that reclassified broadband under Title I, broadband competition has increased. The share of households with high-speed fixed broadband connections offered by three or more providers has increased. Over the same period, entry and intermodal competition from 5G, fixed wireless, and satellite, as discussed in more depth below, has meant that more than 94% of the country can now access high-speed broadband from three or more providers. The growing consumer adoption of technologies that differ substantially from fixed broadband demonstrate that consumers view these technologies as competitive substitutes for each other.

b.        Broadband speeds have increased while prices have declined

Critics of the current state of U.S. broadband competition claim that U.S. prices are among the highest in the developed world because the U.S. market is not as competitive as other jurisdictions. For example, the Community Tech Network asks rhetorically, “So why does the internet cost so much more in the U.S. than in other countries? One possible answer is the lack of competition.”[41] Their article includes a graphic in which U.S. internet is described as “expensive and slow” while Australia is categorized as “fast and cheap.”

None of these claims appear to hold up under scrutiny. Instead, adjusting for consumption and download speeds, U.S. fixed-broadband pricing is among the lowest in the developed world. On a cost-per-megabit basis, the United States is among the least costly (Figure 2).[42] In addition, Speedtest’s Global Index of median speeds reports the United States as having the second-fastest median speed among OECD countries (Figure 3).[43]

 

Cross-country comparisons of broadband pricing are especially fraught, due to country-by-country variations in factors that drive the costs of delivering broadband and the prices paid by consumers. Deployment costs are driven largely by population density and terrain, as well as each country’s unique regulatory and tax policies.[44] Consumer choices often drive the prices paid by subscribers. These include choices regarding the mix of fixed broadband and mobile, speed preferences, and data consumption.[45]

A broadband-pricing index published annually by USTelecom reports that inflation-adjusted broadband prices for the most popular speed tiers among consumers have decreased by 54.7% from 2015 to 2023, or 5.6% a year.[46] Prices for the highest-speed tiers have decreased by 55.8% over the same period. The Producer Price Index for residential internet-access services decreased by 11.2% from 2015 through July 2023.[47] The median fixed-broadband connection in the United States delivers more than 207 Mbps download service, an 80% increase over the pre-pandemic median speed (Figure 4).[48]

An industry experiencing increasing quality along with decreasing prices is consistent with an industry that faces robust, if not increasing, competition. By these measures, the U.S. broadband industry, under Title I regulation, is both competitive and dynamic. To date, proponents of Title II regulation have not demonstrated that net neutrality or other common-carrier obligations have or will improve internet speeds or pricing for consumers.

c.        New technologies have increased intermodal competition

Nearly one-in-eight households with at-home internet are mobile-only.[49] According to Pew Research, 19% of adults who do not have at-home broadband report that their smartphone does everything they need to do online.[50] Even so, the Commission concludes that fixed and mobile internet are not substitutable,[51] and seeks comments regarding its conclusion that, “fixed broadband and mobile wireless broadband are not substitutes in all cases,” as well as its finding that broadband service and mobile-wireless service “enable[] different situational uses.”[52]

“All cases” is an unreasonably high threshold that fails to recognize the central question of competition—namely, how do or would consumers respond to a significant change in prices, quality, or terms and conditions? It’s been long-established that goods and services need not be perfect—or even close—substitutes to exert competitive pressure.[53] Indeed, as we discuss in this section, consumer adoption of 5G and satellite broadband indicate that many consumers view fixed, mobile, and satellite broadband as competitive substitutes. Thus, any FCC evaluation of broadband competition must account for competitive threats and pressures associated with intermodal competition.

One of the most important changes to occur since the last two net-neutrality rounds is the intensification of intermodal competition, primarily due to the introduction and expansion of satellite and fixed-wireless options, alongside the rapid growth of high-speed 5G technology. These developments have not only diversified the array of available services, but also enhanced their quality and accessibility. Moreover, the advent of widely available satellite and fixed-wireless technologies offers viable alternatives to traditional broadband, breaking down previous geographical and infrastructural barriers. Satellite-broadband services, 5G wireless, and fixed wireless now offer robust competition in areas previously served by, at most, one or two fixed-broadband providers. When considering the state of competition in broadband access, acknowledging this growing intermodal competition is crucial.

The advent of low-earth orbit (LEO) satellite broadband has dramatically expanded the geographic reach of high-speed internet access. Starlink satellite service has been made available to all locations in the United States.[54] Starlink’s reported speeds are between 25/5 Mbps and 220/25 Mbps.[55] Project Kuiper has successfully launched its first test satellites,[56] with commercial service expected to begin in the second half of 2024.[57] Starlink and Project Kuiper provide new broadband options, especially for rural and remote households previously limited to slow DSL services. S&P Global Market Intelligence reports:

Satellite broadband subs … have lingered in the 1 million to 2 million subscriber range since 2008 but finally broke above 2 million last year due largely to growth at Low Earth Orbit new entrant Starlink.” [58]

Research published in 2017—two years before the first launch of Starlink satellites—found that households in manufactured or modular homes are more likely to adopt satellite internet instead of wired, cable connections.[59] One explanation is that many manufactured homes are not cable-ready and lack the wiring for cable-internet connections. Thus, despite the higher monthly costs, the “all-in” cost of satellite connections is relatively lower. These consumers clearly considered cable and satellite to be competitors. In research published last month, Gregory Rosston and Scott Wallsten highlighted the importance of satellite broadband for competition in rural areas:

Starlink (and its likely future LEO competitors) are creating real, facilities-based broadband competition in areas that are currently not served by low-latency service or are served only by companies that rely on heavy subsidies. The opportunities, therefore are broadband competition in rural areas and large reductions in taxpayer spending on broadband availability.[60]

Citing estimates from research firm Omdia, the Wall Street Journal reports that about 43% of U.S. consumers had 5G mobile subscriptions as of June 2023.[61] The increasing deployment of 5G wireless technology has led to faster speeds, lower latency, and greater reliability, leading to 5G becoming increasingly competitive with fixed broadband.

  • Recent data reports 5G download speeds of 80.0 Mbps to 195.5 Mbps among the three largest U.S. providers.[62] These speeds are sufficient to support a household of two to five users, streaming high-resolution and 4K video, streaming music, online gaming, remote work, and home-security services.[63] Moreover, these speeds far exceed the FCC’s definition of “high-speed broadband” as speeds of at least 25/3 Mbps.[64]
  • Analysis of Speedtest data by Ericsson finds “the vast majority” of speed tests have measured a latency of less than 50 ms for both 4G and 5G.[65] In comparison, the FCC reports cable latencies of between 13 ms and 26 ms and fiber latencies of between 9 ms and 13 ms.[66]

As the 5G rollout continues and more spectrum is deployed, wireless speeds will continue to increase.[67] And enhancements like 5G fixed-wireless access (FWA) enable carriers to compete directly with wired services. For example, one study concludes:

We find that at current prices, full FWA entry to a cable-only market, which constitutes approximately 30 percent of all cable modem subscribers in the United States, would convert 18 percent of cable-only households to FWA …. In cable/fiber markets, we find that full FWA entry would convert 2 percent of households from cable modem to FWA ….[68]

B.      Title I Enables Business-Model Experimentation and Differentiation

The NPRM assumes that net-neutrality rules assuring an “open Internet” are necessary to promote “edge innovation,” which creates consumer demand for high-speed internet and therefore “expanded investments in broadband infrastructure.”[69] But the NPRM essentially ignores the dynamic competition in broadband markets that leads to significant investment and innovation by broadband providers, as the market since the repeal 2015 Order shows. Part II.B.1 describes this dynamic competition in broadband markets. Part II.B.2 makes the case that Title I classification is what has allowed continued experimentation and innovation by broadband providers.

1.        Broadband markets are characterized by dynamic competition

Potential competition plays a pivotal role in dynamic technology markets. The threat that new technologies like LEO satellite and 5G fixed wireless could disrupt incumbents’ market share stimulates continued infrastructure investment and innovation. Even where substitution currently is incomplete, the looming threat of competitive disruption disciplines behavior.

To this point, as we have previously noted,[70] broadband-market competition should be understood as dynamic, not static. Related to the question of intermodal competition (which can often present imperfect substitutes) are market dynamics driven by potential competition:

In dynamic contexts, potential competitors can have much greater importance. What today appears merely to be a potential competitor can obliterate incumbents tomorrow in acts of Schumpeterian creative destruction. To exclude such a competitor from the boundaries of the market would clearly be a mistake.[71]

Where traditional competition analysis tends to gauge competitiveness using narrow, static indicia such as price levels and market share, a focus on “dynamic competition” may be more appropriate in technology-driven markets like broadband service. Dynamic markets are not typically composed of many competitors making marginal price adjustments to capture small slices of market share. Instead, such markets often experience sequential competition: firms vie to capture the entire market (or most of it), with would-be competitors and new entrants attempting to disrupt incumbents by introducing innovative new products or business models to supplant previous technologies.

An assumption that more concentration must mean less competition stems from a blackboard model of “perfect competition,” where innovation is merely a competitive dimension that emerges from a healthy market structure, rather than innovation driving the evolution of market structures. Rivalry is, of course, important, but no one seriously believes we live in a world of perfect competition characterized by atomistic firms competing to produce commodity goods and services. Yet this simplistic structuralist view of markets is frequently advanced in policy discussions.[72]

As Harold Demsetz famously observed, “the asserted relationship between market concentration and competition cannot be derived from existing theoretical considerations and that it is based largely on an incorrect understanding of the concept of competition or rivalry.”[73] In the case of natural monopolies, scale economies may make it more efficient for one firm to produce a good or service in a given market than it would be for two or more firms. Scale economies arise when high fixed costs are spread over a larger number of goods, allowing larger firms to enjoy lower per-unit costs of production. Due to economies of scale, markets like broadband, with high fixed costs, will tend to have fewer firms than markets with lower fixed costs. But Demsetz demonstrated that, even then, competition for the market itself can lead to an efficient result that prevents the typical welfare harms attributed to monopolies.[74]

The oft-neglected literature on dynamic capabilities and organizational strategy, by contrast, supports the supposition that innovation drives market structure.[75] For the last several decades, this literature has demonstrated that static price-effect-focused analysis is insufficient to understand dynamic markets. For dynamic markets, instead, it is performance that matters, with price as a secondary consideration and innovation as an important component of performance.[76] So long as a market remains contestable, even if it’s highly concentrated, firms’ performance will determine the likelihood of new entrants. It is pressure from those potential new entrants that continues to drive market competitiveness.[77]

Indeed, in highly dynamic economies, particularly those characterized by scale economies, there can be just as much reason to be concerned about too many competitors as by too few. Further, these dynamic markets tend to see a continual rebalancing between equilibrium and disruption:

With dynamic competition, new entrants and incumbents alike engage in new product and process development and other adjustments to change. Frequent new product introductions followed by rapid price declines are commonplace. Innovations stem from investment in R&D or from the improvement and combination of older technologies. Firms continuously introduce product innovations, and from time to time, dominant designs emerge. With innovation, the number of new entrants explodes, but once dominant designs emerge, implosions are likely, and markets become more concentrated. With dynamic competition, innovation and competition are tightly linked.[78]

Thus, in any given market at a given time, there is likely some optimal number of firms that maximizes social welfare.[79] That optimal number—which is sometimes just one and is never the maximum possible—is subject to change, as technological shocks affect the dominant paradigms controlling the market.[80] The optimal number of firms also varies with the strength of scale economies, such that consumers may benefit from an increase in concentration if economies of scale are strong enough.[81] Therefore, in dynamic markets characterized by high fixed costs and strong economies of scale, like broadband markets, the optimal number of firms is reached much more quickly than in, for instance, relatively more commodity-like markets.

Broadband has many of the attributes of a dynamic market, which tends to make static analyses of broadband competition fail to accurately appreciate competitive realities.[82] Broadband markets are driven by technological trends and can be disrupted by rapid modal shifts (e.g., from DSL to cable, or, looking forward, from cable to 5G wireless, satellite, and fixed wireless). Moreover, the infrastructure necessary to deliver broadband requires both long-term planning, as well as substantial sustained investment. Firms in broadband markets are driven not merely by potential entrants today, but by the necessity of intense and expensive planning for future shifts in technology and consumption preferences. Thus, firms operate with an eye toward future competitive pressures, not merely in response to winning market share in the present.

Contrary to some assumptions, the U.S. broadband market is characterized by a significant amount of entry (and exit). As Connolly & Prieger find:

The striking conclusion is that there is a tremendous amount of dynamic activity in the US broadband market. In the national market, the entry rate averages 14-19% annually, which is greater than the entry rates the economic literature has found for many other industries. The exit rate for broadband is also higher than for other industries, but not as high as the entry rate, so that net entry averages 3.1% annually. With narrower geographic or service type market definitions, the entry rates average from 24% to an astounding 49% per annum.[83]

Thus, broadband providers must balance the need to offer attractive pricing in response to immediate competitive pressures with a simultaneous need to make risky and costly investments in technological upgrades in order to compete with advanced technologies that may not be implemented for a decade or more.

Just as market share is a poor indicator of competition, basic accounting measures of profitability and investment often fail to demonstrate how risk/return expectations are realized in dynamic markets over the entire innovation lifecycle. A very large and very profitable ISP may have experienced prior negative returns on invested capital, a result of the need to assume risk and make enormous investments under conditions of uncertainty. The broadband market is constantly evolving as a result of historical and ongoing infrastructure investment, rapidly changing technology, the evolution of content and content-delivery technology, new regulations, and shifting usage patterns, among other factors. Facilities-based competition (e.g., among fiber, cable, mobile, and satellite) has ebbed and flowed depending on these various characteristics, but it has consistently produced higher-quality connectivity at lower quality-adjusted prices. An accurate assessment of competitiveness in broadband markets must take account of all these characteristics.

Further, it is well-known that process and product innovation does not arise solely from new entry; incumbent firms frequently are important sources of innovation, as well as increased market competitiveness.[84] Dynamic analysis does take entry seriously, but it is much more sensitive to potential entry as a constraint on incumbents than a structuralist view would permit. Thus, for example, an incumbent broadband provider that offers a 250 Mbps tier must consider the potential capabilities of an existing competitor that only offers 100 Mbps service; it must incorporate potential threats from that competitor in its decision matrix when evaluating whether to upgrade its network to 1 Gbps in order to retain its customer base. An incumbent’s dominant position can quickly erode thanks to imperfect in-market substitutes, as well as from out-of-market firms that may decide to enter in the future.[85]

2.        Title I classification promotes dynamic competition

The debate surrounding the optimal regulatory framework for broadband services often hinges on finding a balance that fosters innovation and consumer welfare without stifling competition. The broadband industry has thrived, for decades delivering lower prices and faster speeds under a Title I classification.[86] History has demonstrated that a light-touch regulatory regime under Title I of the Communications Act is the most conducive environment to achieve these objectives.

One of the primary functions of a firm is to discover consumer needs, a process that frequently requires firms to “think outside the box.” To attract and retain customers, firms must experiment with offerings that introduce competition from unexpected quarters and keep competitive pressures in place through technological and business-model innovation.

Light-touch regulatory frameworks are inherently more compatible with this approach than are more onerous regimes, like Title II of the Communications Act. For example, in 2011, MetroPCS attempted to introduce a limited data plan offering subsidized, unlimited access to YouTube and other content providers, targeting price-sensitive consumers.[87] This plan, though unconventional, was poised to help bridge the digital divide by making wireless data more accessible to a segment traditionally underserved by larger carriers. This type of business model is a non-neutral form of paid prioritization, but it would very likely have helped price-conscious consumers access more internet services. MetroPCS ultimately abandoned this plan, and such a plan would almost certainly run afoul of the proposed rules in this NPRM.[88]

Since then, ISPs have experimented with other potentially non-neutral paid-prioritization approaches that nonetheless would yield enormous consumer surplus, such as AT&T’s Sponsored Data program[89] and T-Mobile’s Binge On.[90] Such business models provide more choices, potentially lower prices, and introduce competitive threats to other players in the market. Ex ante rules that presumptively ban this kind of experimentation foreclose the ability to discover if such models actually serve the interests of consumers in practice.

And the harms that flow from reduced innovation affect not just ISPs and their consumers, but all parts of the internet ecosystem. As Sidak and Teece have observed:

The lost benefits [of bans on paid prioritization] would affect both end users and suppliers of content and applications. Optional business-to-business transactions for QoS will enhance the efficiency of traffic flow over broadband networks, reducing congestion. That enhanced efficiency benefits both the end users receiving content or applications and the content providers whose content or applications are demanded. Superior QoS is a form of product differentiation, and it therefore increases welfare by increasing the production choices available to content and applications providers and the consumption choices available to end users. Finally, as in other two-sided platforms, optional business-to-business transactions for QoS will allow broadband network operators to reduce subscription prices for broadband end users, promoting broadband adoption by end users, which will increase the value of the platform for all users.[91]

This follows from the nature of ISPs as platforms sitting at the center of a two-sided market. On one side are end users who pay the ISP for access to the internet; on the other are content providers who want access to the end users. A ban on paid prioritization assures that the ISP can monetize only one side of the market. Aside from putting upward pricing pressure on end consumers, this also has a detrimental effect on the overall value of the platform for users and content providers alike.

Prescriptive ex ante regulations under Title II amount to per se bans on certain conduct, without even inquiring whether such conduct is a net harm. Antitrust law, which is sensitive to exactly the sort of vertical harms that are the subject of concern in this NPRM,[92] has developed rule-of-reason analysis to parse when challenged conduct is harmful to consumer welfare.[93] That is, antitrust law does not assume that vertical restraints always harm consumers, but has learned that, in many cases, vertical restraints are a net benefit. But this analysis always occurs ex post, allowing companies to experiment with innovative business models like the many variations of paid prioritization.

C.      Title II Reclassification Introduces Regulatory Uncertainty

The Commission tentatively deems unsubstantiated the 2018 Order’s conclusions that ISP investment is closely tied to the Title II classification.[94] This is because the Commission now concludes that network-infrastructure owners make long-term, irreversible investments and that the adoption of orders reclassifying broadband internet-access services would be unlikely to change these investment decisions. In addition, because the Commission received conflicting viewpoints on the actual effect of Title II classification on investment, it concludes that no one can “quantify with any reasonable degree of accuracy how either a Title I or a Title II approach may affect future investment.”[95] Instead, the Commission tentatively concludes that changes in ISP investment following adoption of reclassification orders were more likely related to factors such as economic conditions, technology changes, and general business decisions, rather than to Title I or Title II classification.[96] The Commission seeks comments on these findings, beliefs, and conclusions.

Put simply, Title II reclassification will hinder investment. The see-sawing between Title I and Title II regulation over the years has already injected regulatory uncertainty into the broadband market. Reimposing Title II regulations will inject additional uncertainty.[97] This uncertainty is compounded by the FCC’s recent digital-discrimination rules. Title II combined with digital discrimination imposes a double whammy of ex ante regulation of some conduct, combined with ex post monitoring, scrutiny, and enforcement of vast array of other conduct.[98]

Firms’ investment decisions are often likened to a pipeline. But a more appropriate analogy would be an assembly line, where investment opportunities are investigated and evaluated. Opportunities with negative returns on investment are rejected and those with positive returns are further evaluated and ranked. Because firms have limited resources, some of the investments with positive returns are rejected. Once a firm decides to pursue an investment opportunity, the project is further evaluated throughout the deployment timeframe. Just as a product can be pulled from the assembly line for defects, investments can be pulled for economic or technical defects. Generally speaking, the further down the assembly line the project goes, the less likely it is to be pulled. Thus, an interruption at the end of the assembly line is likely to be less disruptive than an interruption at the beginning.

In this sense, the Commission is correct to conclude that Title II classification would have relatively less impact on investments that are near the end of their assembly line. But that observation misses the much bigger picture of investments at the beginning of the assembly line and potential investments that are still in the investigation and evaluation stage. For these projects, Title II classification can turn projects with positive expected returns into projects with negative expected returns. In addition, the regulatory uncertainty that is endemic to Title II regulation reduces firms’ confidence in the reliability of their return-on-investment projections. Because of the well-known and widely accepted risk-return tradeoff, firms facing increased uncertainty in investment returns will demand higher expected returns from the investments they pursue.[99]

Put simply, Title II classification may not have a significant effect on investments near completion, but could have a statistically and economically significant impact on future and early-stage investments. Recently published peer-reviewed research supports this conclusion.

Wolfgang Briglauer and his co-authors examine the impact of net-neutrality regulations on broadband-network investment, specifically fiber-optic networks in OECD countries.[100] Roslyn Layton and Mark Jamison describe Briglauer, et al.’s research as “the only empirical, non-anecdotal analysis of net neutrality and investment to date.”[101] Using panel data from 2000 through 2021, Briglauer and his co-authors find evidence that net-neutrality regulations have a significant negative impact on fiber-optic network investment by internet service providers. They employ several econometric techniques, including fixed effects and instrumental variables models, to establish evidence of a causal relationship between net-neutrality rules and reduced investment. The main finding is that the introduction of net-neutrality regulations leads to an estimated 22-25% decrease in new fiber-optic network investments by ISPs.

Briglauer et al. argue their statistical analysis provides evidence that strict net-neutrality rules tend to slow deployment of new high-speed broadband connections. They find the negative impact manifests with a delay, rather than immediately, likely due to rigidities and lags in broadband-deployment projects, thus pointing to a long-run effect. In addition, their fiber investment variable measures newly installed fiber connections, representing new broadband-infrastructure capacity. This is more indicative of long-run capital investment rather than short-run variations in spending.

Briglauer et al. control for other factors unrelated to net-neutrality regulations by including macroeconomic conditions relevant for investment decisions, such as long-term interest rates and a measure of investment freedom. They also control for deployment costs, measured by population density and wages. In addition, their statistical model includes measures of cable competition, mobile competition, telecommunications services prices, and the number of broadband subscriptions. In many cases, these control variables have a statistically significant relationship with fiber investment. Nevertheless, even controlling for these other factors, the authors found that net-neutrality regulations were associated with decreased fiber-optic network investments by ISPs.

The Commission concludes that “changes in ISP investment following the adoption of each Order were more likely the result of other factors unrelated to the classification of BIAS, such as broader economic conditions.”[102] In this framing, it seems the Commission is arguing that if something contributes “more” (however “more” is measured) to investment than Title II classification, then the Commission should conclude that classification has no effect. But this is the wrong framing. Using statistical analysis, the effect of net-neutrality regulations on investment can be estimated while controlling for these other variables. The fact that other variables also affect investment does not invalidate a finding that net-neutrality regulations have some statistically and economically significant negative relationship with investment.

D.     Title II Would Deter Future Innovation in Business Models

1.        Paid prioritization is an essential component of many online business models

The Commission proposes to ban paid or affiliated prioritization arrangements, concluding such arrangements harm consumers, competition, and innovation, as well as creating disincentives to promote broadband deployment.”[103] Chair Rosensworcel has characterized paid prioritization as creating “fast lanes that favor those who can pay for access.”[104] This framing invites the question that was raised years ago, “Do fast lanes mean there are, by definition, slow lanes?”[105] The answer is “no,” as explained by Vox:

An ISP’s bandwidth is not fixed at current levels: As MVPDs shift to all-digital infrastructures, they have significant capacity to dedicate a larger portion of their “pipes” to broadband, which can meaningfully increase bandwidth available to consumers from today’s levels.

Think of bandwidth as a highway: If an entirely new lane is added at the ISP’s expense, that does not harm anyone riding along on the preexisting highway. We struggle to understand why enabling an “extra” HOV lane is bad policy that requires government regulation.

One should not simply assume that the creation of fast lanes of dedicated bandwidth forces everyone else who chooses not to pay ISPs, or cannot pay ISPs, into slow lanes. While those lanes may be slower than the fast lanes, they were slower with or without the fast lanes.

And if bandwidth-heavy traffic that would have traveled over the open Internet (adding to congestion) is offloaded onto a separate fast lane that does not impair the preexisting pipe’s bandwidth capabilities, it should actually ease congestion on the existing lanes, rather than create slow lanes.[106]

Prioritization is a longstanding and widespread practice and, as discussed at length in The Verge regarding Netflix’s Open Connect technology, the internet can’t work without some form of it:

When Open Connect originally launched a decade ago, the service started working collaboratively with ISPs on deployment. Netflix provides ISPs with the servers for free, and Netflix has an internal reliability team that works with ISP resources to maintain the servers. The benefit to ISPs, according to both Netflix and Akamai, is fewer costs to ISPs by alleviating the need for them to have to fetch copies of content themselves.[107]

Indeed, the Verge piece makes clear that even paid prioritization can be an essential tool for edge providers. As we’ve previously noted, paid prioritization offers an economically efficient means to distribute the costs of network optimization.[108]

Axel Gautier and Robert Somogyi developed a model that includes both paid prioritization and zero rating and conclude:

Prioritization is the preferred option of both the ISP and consumers under severe congestion and high-value content, because the low price charged by the ISP to consumers is counterbalanced by large payments from the [content providers].[109]

Banning paid prioritization forces all data to be treated equally, even if customers or services would benefit from differentiated offerings. Without flexibility in how services are delivered and priced, companies lose incentives to develop better networks and new innovations for specific use cases like high-bandwidth video streaming or remote medical services.

  1. Throttling is an effective traffic-management tool

The Commission proposes to ban throttling lawful content, applications, services, and nonharmful devices.[110] While the Commission notes that throttling is “not outright blocking,” it also concludes such conduct “can have the same effects as outright blocking.”[111] The proposed ban would not ban throttling when it is “based on a choice clearly made by the end user,” such as a consumer’s choice of a plan in which a set amount of data is provided at one speed tier and any remaining data is provided at a lower tier.[112]

Internet bandwidth is a scarce and congestible resource subject to wild swings in consumer use. For example, Taylor Swift’s 2023 U.S. concerts have been associated with record-breaking levels of 5G data use on AT&T’s network.[113] Thus, allowing application-specific throttling gives companies incentives to streamline data demands. For mobile networks, excessive data usage impacts spectrum resources available to other customers. If networks cannot limit bandwidth-hungry apps during busy periods, then smartphone app developers lose incentives to tighten data usage. As internet-video traffic occupies about two-thirds of bandwidth, networks need some ability to manage congestion.[114] Outright throttling bans, rather than specific rules against anticompetitive discrimination, eliminate useful tools.

There is a dearth of empirical research regarding the throttling of application-service providers. In the only known published academic research, Daeho Lee and Junseok Hwang categorize application-service providers into four groups by bandwidth-usage attributes and latency sensitivity.[115] Using data from South Korea, they test the hypothesis that ISPs would be more likely to discriminate against content providers needing more bandwidth and more sensitive to latency. A regression of estimated technology-gap ratios on these variables, however, shows no significance, suggesting that ISPs do not discriminate against content providers based on bandwidth usage or latency. Using crowdsourced measurements across 2,735 ISPs in 183 countries and regions, Li et al. find that U.S. mobile providers seem to throttle content providers, but not to the extent in which consumers would likely notice.[116]

On the consumer side, recent research published in Telecommunications Policy finds no evidence that subscribers change their behavior in the face of throttled data rates.[117] Christoph Bauner and Augusto Espin analyze throughput levels measured for mobile ISPs in the United States with usage data to evaluate how sensitive users are to throttling. Using regression analysis of app usage on various measures of throttling, Bauner & Espin find no significant effect of data throughput on app usage. They argue that users may benefit from a modest degree of throttling when it aids network stability and reliability.[118] Bauner & Espin conclude their finding “seemingly weakens the … argument in favor of net neutrality rules.”[119]

In another consumer study, Hyun Ji Lee and Brian Whitacre found that low-income users were willing to pay for an extra GB of data each month, but were not willing to pay extra for a higher speed.[120] This is likely because, if a subscriber has a higher data limit, then they have a lower chance of being throttled for exceeding the cap. Lee & Whitacre’s results indicate Lifeline consumers are willing to pay for the option to use more unthrottled data, but are not willing to pay for higher speeds at all levels of data usage. This data-speed tradeoff suggests those consumers would benefit from a plan that offered a larger data allowance, but throttled speeds if the allowance is exceeded.

If, in fact, ISPs do not generally engage in throttling application-service providers and, when throttling does happen, consumers do not significantly change their usage in the face of throttling, then a ban on throttling is a solution in search of problem. In fact, it could be a solution that is worse than any perceived problem. A ban on data throttling removes essential network-management tools that could prevent congestion and improve overall customer experience. Moreover, discrimination against specific applications or competing services can already be scrutinized under existing antitrust and consumer-protection laws, as discussed in Part III.

  1. Data caps and usage-based pricing can benefit both consumers and providers

In addition to the Commission’s proposed rules prohibiting throttling, the agency is also investigating data caps and usage-based pricing (UBP).[121] A 2021 survey reports that, during the pandemic, 37% of those surveyed hit their data cap, and 68% of those who exceeded their data-cap limit paid overage fees.[122]

Data caps and UBP are not a new issue. In 2013, an FCC advisory committee issued a report on data caps and UBP.[123] That report identified several ways in which the policies improve network performance, consumer experience, and investment and innovation among ISPs and edge providers:

  • Data caps allow ISPs to employ various forms of price discrimination to recover the substantial fixed costs of building broadband networks. Without the ability to charge heavier users more through caps or usage-based pricing, ISPs lose flexibility in designing business models that align costs and willingness-to-pay. This could hamper their incentives and financial ability to continue investing in next-generation network upgrades.
  • The ability to implement data caps or UBP provides incentive for internet application and edge service providers to develop more efficient ways of delivering data-intensive services. For example, data caps may “encourage edge providers to innovate more efficient means of delivering their services” by optimizing video compression algorithms and streamlining data transfers. Removing the possibility of caps or UBP eliminates a motivation for driving such innovation on the edge provider side.
  • Prohibiting data caps or UBP would restrict future business-model experimentation between ISPs and consumers in response to evolving internet-usage patterns and demands. As technology enables new bandwidth-hungry apps and consumer behavior shifts, a strict ban on caps limits the pricing and service optionsthat ISPs can explore to sustainably meet that demand.[124]

While the NPRM is silent on data caps and UBP, the 2015 Order noted that data caps “may benefit consumers by offering them more choices over a greater range of service options,” but left open the possibility of future regulation:[125]

The record also reflects differing views over some broadband providers’ practices with respect to usage allowances (also called “data caps”). … Usage allowances may benefit consumers by offering them more choices over a greater range of service options, and, for mobile broadband networks, such plans are the industry norm today, in part reflecting the different capacity issues on mobile networks. Conversely, some commenters have expressed concern that such practices can potentially be used by broadband providers to disadvantage competing over-the-top providers. Given the unresolved debate concerning the benefits and drawbacks of data allowances and usage-based pricing plans, we decline to make blanket findings about these practices and will address concerns under the no-unreasonable interference/disadvantage on a case-by-case basis.[126]

Gus Hurwitz points out that data caps are a way of offering lower-priced services to lower-need users.[127] They are also a way of apportioning the cost of those networks in proportion to the intensity of a given user’s usage. He notes that, if all users faced the same prices regardless of their usage, there would be no marginal cost to incremental usage. Thus, users and content providers would have little incentive to consider their bandwidth usage. Network congestion does not go away by lifting data caps. Instead, it may be worsened, especially if there is no additional cost associated with additional usage.

As we note above, Lee & Whitacre found that low-income consumers were willing to pay for an extra GB of data each month, but were not willing to pay extra for a higher speed.[128] This indicates that even Lifeline subscribers have a positive willingness-to-pay for a greater data allowance.

Regardless of the effects of prohibiting data caps or UBP on consumers and providers, the more pernicious risk is the legal uncertainty of these practices under Title II regulation. Although the NPRM does not identify any specific proposals regarding data caps or UBP, there is a strong likelihood that these practices could be scrutinized or regulated under the overly broad proposed “conduct rules.” For example, Scott Jordan provides a thorough review of possible data-cap practices and which ones might fall afoul of the 2015 Order.[129] He concludes:

  • Heavy-users caps on mobile-broadband service would likely satisfy the Order’s rules;
  • Profit-maximizing caps on mobile-broadband service may or may not satisfy the rules; and
  • Caps on fixed-broadband service are unlikely to satisfy the rules.

Jordan’s comprehensive survey demonstrates that many data-cap practices are in a gray zone of uncertainty regarding whether they would or would not satisfy the FCC’s conduct rules. This uncertainty would, by itself, likely stifle experimentation with innovative business models and practices, thereby hindering investment and diminishing users’ experiences.

III.    Existing Policies Protect Consumers, National Security, and Public Safety

The Commission seeks comments on whether consumer-protection and antitrust laws provide sufficient protections against blocking, throttling, paid prioritization, and “other conduct that harms the open Internet.][130] In this section, we note that the United States has a multiplicity of agencies, laws, regulations, and rules that span competition, consumer-protection, and national-security issues. The Commission has provided little to no evidence that the existing regulatory regime has been deficient in enforcing existing policies or that new policies are needed—particularly outside of a congressional mandate.

A.      Antitrust and Consumer Protection

Fundamental to the Commission’s position in the 2018 Order was the reasonable conclusion that ensuring ISPs do not interfere with consumers’ access to content over the internet would best be effected by adopting a competition and consumer-protection oriented approach. This is consistent with the Commission’s historical, deregulatory approach to information services, including in the 2015 Order. Since 2018, nothing has changed to disturb the soundness of this approach.

Core to the distinction in these approaches is an evaluation of the appropriate way to judge risk.  The 2015 Order was premised on the theory that because ISPs have any incentive and ability to engage in problematic conduct, they thus will very likely engage in that conduct.[131]  The Commission used this assumption to justify strong ex ante regulation to curtail such expected conduct. In the 2018 Order, rather than simply presuming harm, the Commission undertook an extensive, thorough, and fact-based analysis to first assess the likely risk of harm.[132] Based on this analysis, the Commission concluded that the risk of harmful conduct was low, in terms of both the likelihood that ISPs will engage in such conduct and its potential adverse effects on consumers. Because this risk is low, the Commission reasonably determined that a “light touch” ex post competition-oriented regulatory approach was preferable to the ex ante prescriptive rules adopted in the 2015 Order and under consideration in this NPRM.

We believe that the Commission had the better analysis in 2018 and should continue to support this approach. Indeed, in the long history of the net-neutrality debates, the justifications for imposing Title II obligations on ISPs have been rooted in the precautionary principle, with little or no actual evidence produced demonstrating any intentional violation of “neutrality” principles. And since 2018, no other evidence has been produced.

The ideal regulatory framework for dealing with potential violations of neutrality principles is an ex post regulatory approach that reflects well-established competition law principles and is commensurate with the actual degree of risk and extent of harm associated with ISP misconduct, while also mitigating against the risk that over-regulation that would harm consumers by curtailing pro-competitive ISP activity.

As the Commission observed in the 2018 Order, “[t]he Communications Act includes an antitrust savings clause, so the antitrust laws apply with equal vigor to entities regulated by the Commission.”[133] Thus, the Commission has already struck the proper balance between indirect antitrust enforcement and direct regulation under the Communications Act, which incorporates competition policy as the generally applicable regulatory “default” in the absence of specific statutory mandates. As Justice Breyer has observed, “[r]egulation is viewed as a substitute for competition, to be used only as a weapon of last resort—as a heroic cure reserved for a serious disease.”[134]

Of course, the Communications Act does not speak directly to “net neutrality” harms. But to the extent the act permits the Commission to regulate in this area, it does so largely by requiring the agency to choose between Title I and Title II classifications, reserving Title II for circumstances where the Commission determines that the risk of harm from providers is sufficiently great that ex ante, prescriptive regulation is appropriate—“as a heroic cure reserved for a serious disease.”[135]

Moreover, the Commission’s prior efforts to promote net neutrality overlap substantially, if not entirely, with concerns over ISPs engaging in anticompetitive conduct. In the 2018 Order, the Commission specifically noted that this was a necessary logical justification for its previous order, observing that: “The premise of Title II and other public utility regulation is that ISPs can exercise market power sufficient to substantially distort economic efficiency and harm end users.”[136]

In the 2015 Order, the Commission acknowledged that “[c]ommitment to robust competition and open networks defined Commission policy at the outset of the digital revolution,”[137] and that “[t]he principles of open access, competition, and consumer choice embodied in Carterfone and the Computer Inquires have continued to guide Commission policy in the Internet era[.]”[138]  Likewise, the Commission explicitly acknowledged in the 2015 Order that its asserted authority under Section 706 was based, at least in part, on a mandate to promote competition.[139] Most tellingly, in a section titled “Competitive Effects,” the Commission noted that:

As the Commission has found previously, broadband providers have incentives to interfere with and disadvantage the operation of third-party Internet-based services that compete with the providers’ own services. Practices that have anti-competitive effects in the market for applications, services, content, or devices would likely unreasonably interfere with or unreasonably disadvantage edge providers’ ability to reach consumers in ways that would have a dampening effect on innovation, interrupting the virtuous cycle.  As such, these anticompetitive practices are likely to harm consumers’ and edge providers’ ability to use broadband Internet access service to reach one another . . . .[140]

Thus, as the Commission itself acknowledged in the 2015 Order, competition—and, by implication, anticompetitive behavior of ISPs—is one of the core concerns that drove development of internet policy. Indeed, in the present NPRM, much of the feared harms mentioned are largely derived from vertical foreclosure theory. Namely, they stem from the classic antitrust concern that dominant firms in a vertical supply chain may foreclose competitors from access to consumers, or extract supracompetitive prices from input providers.[141] For example, the NPRM declares that:

[W]e also propose to reinstate rules that prohibit ISPs from blocking or throttling the information transmitted over their networks or engaging in paid or affiliated prioritization arrangements. Additionally, we propose to reinstate a general conduct standard that would prohibit practices that cause unreasonable interference or unreasonable disadvantage to consumers or edge providers.[142]

These instances of potential ISP misconduct raise straightforward antitrust concerns with vertical conduct, squarely within the purview of antitrust law.[143] Importantly, antitrust enforcers and courts—following antitrust economists—assess these vertical restraints under the rule of reason, avoiding their presumptive condemnation because they only rarely result in actual anticompetitive harm.[144]

Under this approach, the effects of potentially harmful conduct are typically evaluated and weighed against the various aims that competition law seeks to promote; only following that review is it determined whether particular conduct is harmful and, if so, whether there are procompetitive benefits that outweigh the harm.

In fact, only a few types of conduct are presumptively condemned, and then only when experience has demonstrated that they are more-often-than-not harmful.[145] Vertical restraints are never evaluated under this per se standard.[146] With such a competition framework for assessing conduct that might threaten “Internet openness,” the Commission would be well-positioned to detect and remedy harmful conduct.

B.      The Transparency Rule Is Adequate for Consumer Protection

One of the longstanding policies available to protect consumers is the Commission’s transparency rule. The existing transparency rule, as upheld by the D.C. Circuit in Verizon v. FCC, mandates that broadband internet-access service providers disclose network-management practices, performance, and commercial terms.[147] This rule, applicable to both fixed and mobile providers, is integral for enabling consumers and edge providers to make informed choices. This rule has, in one form or another, been operational since 2010, and has served as a valuable consumer-protection measure.

The Commission is, however, considering extending this rule in a number of ways. It’s important to keep in mind that no policy extended indefinitely presents an unalloyed good: even transparency requirements, taken too far, can bring more costs than benefits.[148] For example, the proposed enhancements include more tailored disclosures to various stakeholders—including consumers, edge providers, and the FCC[149]—that, despite best intentions, may impose significant costs in the form of compliance burdens on ISPs, while doing little if anything to inform consumers meaningfully.

Additionally, a rule change that leads to the publication of information like pricing will functionally resemble a de facto tariff system. Tariffing, however, is a core component of common carriage.[150] Thus, if the Commission opts not to reclassify under Title II, imposition of such a de facto tariff could be a violation of Section 706. Moreover, regulatory pressure to report pricing in uniform ways could lead to uniform pricing, which, though benign-sounding, could lead to downstream changes in service level and pricing that do not ultimately increase consumer welfare.

For example, although at times difficult to follow, internet-service pricing that is designed around discounts and incentives could be used to benefit economically vulnerable consumers and attract or retain them through a form of price discrimination. If, however, rates converge on a uniform schedule, it is possible that these forms of discounts and incentives will disappear, and that pricing will reflect a mean that is more difficult for lower-income consumers. This possibility has increased substantially with the FCC’s recently adopted digital-discrimination rules, which explicitly subject pricing, discounts, incentives and other terms and conditions to scrutiny and enforcement under the rules.[151] Thus, even in the absence of Title II regulation, the proposed reporting requirements can work hand-in-hand with the digital-discrimination rules to regulate rates in the direction of uniform pricing across providers, thereby limiting the scope of competition for broadband services.

Further, the utility of certain disclosures, such as those related to network congestion, is also questionable. The Commission opted to forego requiring disclosures related to network performance in the 2015 Order.[152]  The Commission should continue in this manner, as such requirements are even less useful today than they were in 2015. With the availability of speed-test applications, consumers already possess tools to assess the performance of their ISP, casting doubt on the additional value of mandatory congestion disclosures.

IV.    Title II Reclassification Will Present Significant Legal Challenges for the Commission

In the NPRM, the FCC asks whether and how the major questions doctrine (MQD) should inform its conclusions on the text and structure of the Communications Act.[153] With the FCC yet again seeking to reclassify broadband, it is worth noting that, since courts have consistently found the Communications Act is ambiguous as to the proper classification of broadband, there are reasons to doubt whether courts would allow this Title II reclassification as compatible with the MQD.

The MQD, as developed by the Supreme Court, stands for the proposition that agencies will not receive deference while interpreting ambiguous statutory language of “vast economic and political significance.”[154] The MQD requires that Congress give an agency clear congressional authorization to act in such cases. In other words, an ambiguous grant of authority is not enough.

In three recent cases, the Supreme Court has struck down major agency actions due to reliance on ambiguous statutory provisions.

In Ala. Ass’n of Realtors v. Dep’t of Health & Human Servs.,[155] the Court rejected the Centers for Disease Control and Prevention’s (CDC) attempt to impose a moratorium upon residential evictions due to COVID-19. The Court emphasized that “[e]ven if the text were ambiguous, the sheer scope of the CDC’s claimed authority… would counsel against the Government’s interpretation.”[156] Instead, the Court required “Congress to speak clearly when authorizing an agency to exercise powers of ‘vast economic and political significance.’”[157] The Court was concerned that the government’s reading of the statute would give them “a breathtaking amount of authority” with virtually “no limit… beyond the requirement that CDC deem a measure ‘necessary.’”[158]

In NFIB v. Dep’t of Labor,[159] the Court found the Occupational Safety and Health Administration (OSHA) could not pass a vaccine mandate for workplaces. Quoting Realtors, the Court noted that Congress must “speak clearly when authorizing and agency to exercise powers of vast economic and political significance.”[160] Since the vaccine mandate was “a significant encroachment into the lives—and health—of a vast number of employees,” it had vast economic and political significance.[161] Therefore, since the statute did not “plainly authorize[] the Secretary’s mandate,” OSHA’s rule was unlawful.[162] The Court found the MQD was important, because it limited agencies’ ability to “exploit some gap, ambiguity, or doubtful expression in Congress’s statutes to assume responsibilities far beyond its initial assignment.”[163]

In West Virginia v. EPA,[164] the Court considered a rulemaking by the Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) on emission limits for power plants. After reviewing the caselaw back to Brown & Williamson through Gonzalez, UARG, Burwell, Realtors, and NFIB,[165] the Court concluded that there was an “identifiable body of law that has developed over a series of significant cases all addressing a particular and recurring problem: agencies asserting highly consequential power beyond what Congress could reasonably be understood to have granted.”[166] The Court found it was clearly a major question, because the EPA had changed a longstanding practice in how it operated under the statute by expanding its power to “unprecedented” levels through a little-used statutory grant of authority.[167] This is despite the fact the agency had asked Congress for increased authority to do exactly what it decided to do under this provision.[168] Since there was no “clear Congressional authorization” for such a rule, the Court struck it down under the MQD.[169]

In sum, the MQD is now recognized by the Supreme Court as an important limit on agency action. If the statutory authority relied upon by the agency is ambiguous and the agency action is of vast economic and political significance, then courts will find the agency action unlawful on grounds that it exceeds the authority granted by Congress. As the Court put it in NFIB:

Why does the major questions doctrine matter? It ensures that the national government’s power to make the laws that govern us remains where Article I of the Constitution says it belongs—with the people’s elected representatives. If administrative agencies seek to regulate the daily lives and liberties of millions of Americans, the doctrine says, they must at least be able to trace that power to a clear grant of authority from Congress.[170]

Here, reclassification of broadband as a Title II telecommunications service would clearly be an exercise of powers of vast economic and political significance. Broadband providers have invested billions of dollars annually into building out reliable high-speed networks throughout the country, serving hundreds of millions of consumers.[171] On top of that, both federal and state governments have supported this continued buildout through subsidies.[172] The NPRM, which closely mirrors the rules from the 2015 Order, would further affect the expected returns on investment from both broadband providers and policymakers.[173] As then-Judge Brett Kavanaugh put it when considering the 2015 OIO, the “FCC’s net neutrality rule is a major rule for the purposes of The Supreme Court’s major rules doctrine. Indeed, I believe that proposition is indisputable.”[174]

It is worth noting that, much like the agency actions in Realtor and NFIB, the scope of authority claimed by the FCC through reclassification is staggering, allowing the Commission to regulate nearly the entire internet infrastructure through Title II’s expansive regulatory provisions. And as in West Virginia, Congress has considered and rejected net-neutrality legislation that would give the FCC clear authority to impose such rules.

Moreover, the NPRM’s attempt, much like the 2015 Order, to nominally minimize the reach of its claimed authority under Title II through forbearance amounts to rewriting the act to make it more palatable, including by forbearing from rate regulation or network-unbundling requirements. [175]  This is very similar to the attempted “tailoring” by the EPA that the Court rejected in Utility Air Regulatory Group v. EPA.[176]  There, the Tailoring Rule was an attempt to make it such that small entities with the potential to emit greenhouse gasses would not be subject to lawsuits that the act would allow.[177] The Court rejected this attempt to rewrite the statute, concluding that an agency “has no power to ‘tailor’ legislation to bureaucratic policy goals by rewriting unambiguous statutory terms.”[178] Much like the EPA in UARG, the FCC’s “need to rewrite clear provisions of the statute should have alerted” them “that it had taken a wrong interpretive turn.”[179]

Moreover, the ability to forbear under Title II also gives the FCC the ability to stop forbearing once Title II reclassification is made. Thus, the decision to reclassify will have huge economic and political implications, as the public and those regulated will have to pay special attention to the forbearance and possible un-forbearance of the FCC’s decisions going forward.

The concurrence from D.C. Circuit Court of Appeals Judges Sri Srinivasan and David Tatel in US Telecom did not dispute that the rule had vast economic and political significance. The concurrence instead focused on the implications of the Supreme Court’s opinion in National Cable and Telecommn’cs Ass’n v. Brand X Internet Serv., 545 US. 967 (2005).[180] The concurrence concluded essentially that Brand X settled the question by finding the FCC had the authority to make the classification decision.[181]

The problem with this, however, is that the Brand X decision just found that the Communications Act is ambiguous as to whether broadband is a “telecommunications service.”[182] In Brand X, the late Justice Antonin Scalia made the argument in his dissent that the Communications Act defined telecommunications service in a way that unambiguously applied to cable-modem service.[183] If this was the Court’s opinion, then there would be a strong argument that it is settled law that Congress spoke clearly to the issue. But it wasn’t. The majority rejected Justice Scalia’s arguments and found the definition ambiguous. In other words, Brand X did not foreclose a challenge under the MQD.

On the contrary, Brand X, as well as the D.C. Circuit’s decision upholding the 2015 Order[184] and the 2018 Order,[185] all stand for the proposition that the classification of broadband service under the Communications Act is ambiguous. Here, this means that the second part of the MQD, whether Congress clearly spoke to the issue, is a clear no.

To sum up, 1) the MQD is now clearly recognized doctrine by the Supreme Court; 2) the decision to apply Title II to broadband services is a decision of “vast economic and political significance”; and 3) Brand X (and its progeny) stands for the proposition that Congress has not unambiguously spoken to whether broadband service is a telecommunications service under the Communications Act. Therefore, the decision to reclassify broadband service again will likely fail under the MQD.

[1] Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, Safeguarding and Securing the Open Internet, WC Docket No. 23-320 (Sep. 28, 2023) [hereinafter “NPRM”] at ¶ 1.

[2] Brendan Carr, Dissenting Statement of Commissioner Brendan Carr, Safeguarding and Securing the Open Internet, WC Docket No. 23-320, Notice of Proposed Rulemaking (Oct. 19, 2023), available at https://docs.fcc.gov/public/attachments/FCC-23-83A3.pdf (“In other words, utility-style regulation of the Internet was never about improving your online experience—that was just the sheep’s clothing. It was always about government control.”).

[3] Report and Order on Remand, Declaratory Ruling, and Order, In the Matter of Protecting and Promoting the Open Internet, GN Docket No. 14-28 (Mar. 15, 2015) [hereinafter “2015 Order”].

[4] Id.

[5] Id.

[6] Id. at ¶ 3.

[7] See, e.g., Anna-Maria Kovacs, U.S. Broadband Networks Rise to the Challenge of Surging Traffic During the Pandemic, Georgetown University (Jun. 2020), https://georgetown.app.box.com/s/8e76udzd1ic0pyg42fqsc96r1yzkz1jf. See also European Commission, Digital Solutions During the Pandemic (Sep. 2023), https://commission.europa.eu/strategy-and-policy/coronavirus-response/digital-solutions-during-pandemic_en (“To prevent network congestion and to support the enjoyment of digital services, the?European Commission called upon?telecom operators and users to take action and met with the CEOs of the streaming platforms. The streaming platforms were encouraged to offer standard rather than high-definition content, telecom operators were recommended to adopt mitigating measures for continued traffic, and users were advised to apply settings to reduce data consumption, including the use of Wi-Fi.”)

[8] See Infrastructure Investment and Jobs Act, Pub. L. No. 117-58, § 60506 (2021) (Digital Discrimination) [hereinafter “IIJA”].

[9] See Brendan Carr, supra, note 2 (“Congress has already empowered Executive Branch agencies with national security expertise, including the DOJ, DHS, and Treasury, with the lead when it comes to security issues in the communications sector.”)

[10] See, e.g., 2022 Broadband Capex Report, USTelecom (Sep. 8, 2023), https://ustelecom.org/research/2022-broadband-capex (“America’s broadband industry invested a record $102.4 billion in U.S. communications infrastructure in 2022, reflecting broadband providers’ determination to help achieve the national objective of affordable, reliable high-speed connectivity for all. The annual figure represents a 21-year high for investment from the communications sector and a 19% year-over-year increase.”).

[11] US Telecom v. FCC, 855 F.3d 381, 422 (D.C. Cir. 2016) (Kavanaugh, J., dissenting from denial of rehearing en banc).

[12] Cf. National Cable and Telecommn’cs Ass’n v. Brand X Internet Serv., 545 US. 967 (2005); US Telecom v. FCC, 825 F.3d 674 (D.C. Cir. 2016).; Mozilla Corp v. FCC, 940 F.3d 1 (D.C. Cir. 2019).

[13] NPRM at ¶ 3.

[14] Id. at ¶ 116.

[15] Id. at ¶ 122.

[16] See, for example, Bauner & Espin, infra note 116 (regarding throttling, concluding “incentives for such discrimination are not as strong as feared.”)

[17] NPRM at ¶ 17.

[18] See Paul Krugman & Robin Wells, Economics 389 (4th ed. 2015) (“So the natural monopolist has increasing returns to scale over the entire range of output for which any firm would want to remain in the industry—the range of output at which the firm would at least break even in the long run. The source of this condition is large fixed costs: when large fixed costs are required to operate, a given quantity of output is produced at lower average total cost by one large firm than by two or more smaller firms.”)

[19] Id. (“The most visible natural monopolies in the modern economy are local utilities—water, gas, and sometimes electricity. As we’ll see, natural monopolies pose a special challenge to public policy.”)

[20] See Richard H. K. Vietor, Contrived Competition 167 (1994) (“[I]n the early part of the twentieth century, American Telephone and Telegraph (AT&T) set itself the goal of providing universal telephone services through an end-to-end national monopoly. … By [the 1960s], however, the distortions of regulatory cross-subsidy had diverged too far from the economics of technological change.”); see also Thomas W. Hazlett, Cable TV Franchises as Barriers to Video Competition, 2 Va. J.L. & Tech. 1, 1 (2007) (“Traditionally, municipal cable TV franchises were advanced as consumer protection to counter “natural monopoly” video providers. …  Now, marketplace changes render even this weak traditional case moot. … [V]ideo rivalry has proven viable, with inter-modal competition from satellite TV and local exchange carriers (LECs) offering “triple play” services.”)

[21] See id. at 59-73.

[22] Share of United States Households Using Specific Technologies, Our World in Data (n.d.), https://ourworldindata.org/grapher/technology-adoption-by-households-in-the-united-states.

[23] Id. (showing household usage of landlines and mobile phones in 2018 at 42.7% and 95%, respectively).

[24] Edward Carlson, Cutting the Cord: NTIA Data Show Shift to Streaming Video as Consumers Drop Pay-TV, NTIA (2019), https://www.ntia.gov/blog/2019/cutting-cord-ntia-data-show-shift-streaming-video-consumers-drop-pay-tv.

[25] Karl Bode, A New Low: Just 46% Of U.S. Households Subscribe to Traditional Cable TV, TechDirt (Sep. 18, 2023), https://www.techdirt.com/2023/09/18/a-new-low-just-46-of-u-s-households-subscribe-to-traditional-cable-tv. See also Shira Ovide, Cable TV Is the New Landline, N.Y. Times (Jan. 6, 2022), https://www.nytimes.com/2022/01/06/technology/cable-tv.html.

[26] See Stephen Breyer, Regulation and Its Reform 195 (1982).

[27] NPRM at ¶ 127.

[28] Id.

[29] Id.

[30] Id.

[31] See, e.g., Karl Bode, Colorado Eyes Killing State Law Prohibiting Community Broadband Networks, TechDirt (Mar. 30, 2023), https://www.techdirt.com/2023/03/30/colorado-eyes-killing-state-law-prohibiting-community-broadband-networks (Local broadband monopolies are a “widespread market failure that’s left Americans paying an arm and a leg for what’s often spotty, substandard broadband access.”).

[32] FCC Chair Rosenworcel on Reinstating Net Neutrality Rules, C-Span (Sep. 25, 2023), https://www.c-span.org/video/?530731-1/fcc-chair-rosenworcel-reinstating-net-neutrality-rules (“Only one-fifth of the country has more than two choices at [100 Mbps download] speed. So, if your broadband provider mucks up your traffic, messes around with your ability to go where you want and do what you want online, you can’t just pick up and take your business to another provider. That provider may be the only game in town.”).

[33] See FCC, 2015 Broadband Progress Report (2015), https://www.fcc.gov/reports-research/reports/broadband-progressreports/2015-broadband-progress-report (Upgrading the standard speed from 4/1 Mbps to 25/3 Mbps). In November 2023, FCC Chair Rosenworcel announced a notice of inquiry seeking input on a proposal to raise the minimum connection-speed benchmark to 100/20 Mbps, with a goal of having a benchmark of 1000/500 Mbps by the year 2030; See also, Eric Fruits, Gotta Go Fast: Sonic the Hedgehog Meets the FCC, Truth on the Market (Nov. 3, 2023), https://truthonthemarket.com/2023/11/03/gotta-go-fast-sonic-the-hedgehog-meets-the-fcc.

[34] See IIJA at § 60102 (a)(1)(A). See also Jake Varn, What Makes a Community “Unserved” or “Underserved” by Broadband?, Pew Charitable Trusts (May 3, 2023), available at https://www.pewtrusts.org/-/media/assets/2023/06/un–and-underserved-definitions-ta-memo-pdf.pdf.

[35] See IIJA at § 60102(a)(1)(C)(II)(i).

[36] Mike Conlow, New FCC Broadband Map, Version 3, Mike’s Newsletter (Nov. 20, 2023), https://mikeconlow.substack.com/p/new-fcc-broadband-map-version-3.

[37] FCC, Fixed Broadband Deployment (Jun. 2021), https://broadband477map.fcc.gov/#/area-summary?version=jun2021&type=nation&geoid=0&tech=acfw&speed=25_3&vlat=27.480205324799257&vlon=-41.52925368904516&vzoom=5.127403622197149.

[38] FCC, 2019 Broadband Deployment Report, GN Docket No. 18-238, FCC 19-44 (May 29, 2019), at Fig, 4, available at https://docs.fcc.gov/public/attachments/FCC-19-44A1.pdf.

[39] FCC, 2022 Communications Marketplace Report, GN Docket No. 22-203 (Dec. 30, 2022), at Fig. II.A.28, https://docs.fcc.gov/public/attachments/FCC-22-103A1.pdf.

[40] Report and Order on Remand, Declaratory Ruling, and Order, In the Matter of Restoring Internet Freedom WC Docket No. 17-108 (Jan. 4, 2018) [hereinafter “2018 Order”]

[41] Why Is the Internet More Expensive in the USA Than in Other Countries?, Community Tech Network (Feb. 2, 2023), https://communitytechnetwork.org/blog/why-is-the-internet-more-expensive-in-the-usa-than-in-other-countries.

[42] This is qualitatively consistent with the FCC’s finding that United States has the seventh-lowest prices per-gigabit of data consumption. FCC, 2022 Communications Marketplace Report (Appendix G), GN Docket No. 22-103 (Dec. 30, 2022), at 69 (Fig. 41 Fixed Broadband Price Indexes), available at https://docs.fcc.gov/public/attachments/FCC-22-103A5.pdf.

[43] Speedtest, Median Country Speeds Oct. 2023, Speedtest Global Index (last accessed Dec. 11, 2023), https://www.speedtest.net/global-index.

[44] See Eric Fruits & Kristian Stout, The Income Conundrum: Intent and Effects Analysis of Digital Discrimination, Int’l Ctr. for L. & Econ. (Nov. 14, 2022), available at https://laweconcenter.org/wp-content/uploads/2022/11/The-Income-Conundrum-Intent-and-Effects-Analysis-of-Digital-Discrimination.pdf; see also Giuseppe Colangelo, Regulatory Myopia and the Fair Share of Network Costs: Learning from Net Neutrality’s Mistakes, Int’l Ctr. for L. & Econ. (May 18, 2023), https://laweconcenter.org/resources/regulatory-myopia-and-the-fair-share-of-network-costs-learning-from-net-neutralitys-mistakes.

[45] Id.

[46] Arthur Menko, 2023 Broadband Pricing Index, Business Planning Inc., (Oct. 2023), available at https://ustelecom.org/wp-content/uploads/2023/10/USTelecom-2023-BPI-Report-final.pdf.

[47] U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, Producer Price Index by Commodity: Telecommunication, Cable, and Internet User Services: Residential Internet Access Services [WPU374102], retrieved from FRED, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis (Aug. 29, 2023), https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/WPU374102.

[48] Speedtest, United States Median Country Speeds July 2023, Speedtest Global Index (2023), https://www.speedtest.net/global-index/united-states. Prior years retrieved from Internet Archive. See also Camryn Smith, The Average Internet Speed in the U.S. Has Increased by Over 100 Mbps since 2017, AllConnect (Aug. 4, 2023), https://www.allconnect.com/blog/internet-speeds-over-time (average download speed in the United States was 30.7 Mbps in 2017 and 138.9 Mbps in the first half of 2023).

[49] U.S. Census Bureau, 2021 American Community Survey 1-Year Estimates, Table Id. S2801 (2021); U.S. Census Bureau, ACS 1-Year Estimates Public Use Microdata Sample 2021, Access to the Internet (ACCESSINET) (2021).

[50] Andrew Perrin, Mobile Technology and Home Broadband 2021, Pew Research Center (Jun. 3, 2021), https://www.pewresearch.org/internet/2021/06/03/mobile-technology-and-home-broadband-2021.

[51] Id. U.S. Census Bureau, 2021 American Community Survey 1-Year Estimates, Table Id. S2801 (2021); U.S. Census Bureau, ACS 1-Year Estimates Public Use Microdata Sample 2021, Access to the Internet (ACCESSINET) (2021).

[52] NPRM at ¶123 (emphasis added).

[53] See Edward Chamberlin, The Theory of Monopolistic Competition (1933) (arguing that even if a competitor’s service is not a perfect substitute, it can still exert competitive pressure by appealing to different segments of the market with different preferences.). See also William J. Baumol, Contestable Markets: An Uprising in the Theory of Industry Structure, 72 Am. Econ. Rev. (1982) (arguing that even if a new entrant’s product is not a perfect substitute for the incumbent’s product, it can still exert competitive pressure by threatening to enter the market and erode the incumbent’s market share.)

[54] See Dan Heming, Starlink No Longer Has a Waitlist for Standard Service, and 10 MPH Speed Enforcement Update, Mobile Internet Resource Center (Oct. 3, 3023), https://www.rvmobileinternet.com/starlink-no-longer-has-a-waitlist-for-standard-service-and-10-mph-speed-enforcement-update.

[55] See Starlink Specifications, Starlink (last accessed Dec. 12, 2023), https://www.starlink.com/legal/documents/DOC-1400-28829-70.

[56] See Amazon Staff, Amazon Shares an Update on How Project Kuiper’s Test Satellites are Performing, Amazon (Oct. 16, 2023), https://www.aboutamazon.com/news/innovation-at-amazon/amazon-project-kuiper-test-satellites-space-launch-october-2023-update.

[57] See Kuiper Service to Start by End of 2024: Amazon, Communications Daily (Oct. 12, 2023), https://communicationsdaily.com/news/2023/10/12/Kuiper-Service-to-Start-by-End-of-2024-Amazon-2310110007.

[58] John Fletcher, The History of US Broadband, S&P Global Market Intelligence (May 23,2023), https://www.spglobal.com/marketintelligence/en/news-insights/research/the-history-of-us-broadband. The report also notes, “While fixed wireless similarly had trouble breaking above 2 million subscribers for years, its recent surge, driven by T-Mobile US Inc. and Verizon, helped it surpass 6 million last year.” Id.

[59] See Andre Boik, The Economics of Universal Service: An Analysis of Entry Subsidies for High Speed Broadband, 40 Info. Econ. & Pol’y 13 (2017).

[60] Gregory Rosston & Scott Wallsten, Should Satellite Broadband Be Included in Universal Service Subsidy Programs?, 6 J. L. & Innovation 135 (2023).

[61] See Drew FitzGerald, After More Than Four Years, Has 5G Lived Up to Expectations?, Wall St. J. (Oct. 14, 2023), https://www.wsj.com/business/telecom/how-5g-changed-world-752b13ee.

[62] See Robert Wyrzykowski, 5G Experience Report, OpenSignal (Jul. 2023), https://www.opensignal.com/reports/2023/07/usa/mobile-network-experience-5g; Petroc Taylor, Average 5G and Overall Download Speed by Provider in the United States in 2023 (in Mbps), Statista (Jul. 11, 2023), https://www.statista.com/statistics/818204/4g-3g-and-overall-download-speed-in-the-united-states-by-provider.

[63] See Robin Layton, Everything You Need to Know About Internet Speeds, AllConnect (Aug. 9, 2023), https://www.allconnect.com/blog/consumers-guide-to-internet-speed.

[64] See FCC, 2015 Broadband Progress Report (2015), https://www.fcc.gov/reports-research/reports/broadband-progressreports/2015-broadband-progress-report (upgrading the standard speed from 4/1 Mbps to 25/3 Mbps). In November 2023, FCC Chair Rosenworcel week announced a notice of inquiry seeking input on a proposal to raise the minimum connection-speed benchmark to 100/20 Mbps, with a goal of having a benchmark of 1000/500 Mbps by the year 2030; See Eric Fruits, Gotta Go Fast: Sonic the Hedgehog Meets the FCC, Truth on the Market (Nov. 3, 2023), https://truthonthemarket.com/2023/11/03/gotta-go-fast-sonic-the-hedgehog-meets-the-fcc.

[65] Reiner Ludwig, Who Cares About Latency in 5G?, Ericsson Blog (Aug. 16, 2022), https://www.ericsson.com/en/blog/2022/8/who-cares-about-latency-in-5g.

[66] FCC, Measuring Fixed Broadband—Eleventh Report (Dec. 31, 2021), https://www.fcc.gov/reports-research/reports/measuring-broadband-america/measuring-fixed-broadband-eleventh-report.

[67] See, Eli Blumenthal, Verizon’s 5G Speeds Are About to Get Faster, Ahead of Schedule, CNET (Aug. 14, 2023), https://www.cnet.com/tech/mobile/verizons-5g-speeds-are-about-to-get-faster-ahead-of-schedule.

[68] Hal Singer & Augustus Urschel, Competitive Effects of Fixed Wireless Access on Wireline Broadband Technologies, Econ One (Jun. 2023), available at https://api.ctia.org/wp-content/uploads/2023/06/Competitive-Effects-of-Fixed-Wireless-Access-on-Wireline-Broadband-Technologies-FINAL.pdf.

[69] NPRM at ¶129.

[70] This section is adapted from Geoffrey A. Manne, Kristian Stout & Ben Sperry, A Dynamic Analysis of Broadband Competition: What Concentration Numbers Fail to Capture, at 26-30, Int. Ctr. for L. & Econ. (Jun. 3, 2021), available at https://laweconcenter.org/wp-content/uploads/2021/06/A-Dynamic-Analysis-of-Broadband-Competition.pdf.

[71] See J. Gregory Sidak & David J. Teece, Dynamic Competition in Antitrust Law, 5 J. Competition L. & Econ. 581, 614 (2009).

[72] C.f. id. at 585 (“Indeed, it is common to find a debate about innovation policy among economists collapsing into a rather narrow discussion of the relative virtues of competition and monopoly, as if they were the main determinants of innovation. Clearly, much more is at work.”).

[73] Harold Demsetz, Why Regulate Utilities?, 11 J. L. & Econ. 55, 55 (1968).

[74] See id.

[75] See Sidak & Teece, Dynamic Competition, supra note 71.

[76] See, e.g., Thomas M. Jorde & David J. Teece, Competing Through Innovation: Implications for Market Definition, 64 Chi.-Kent L. Rev. 741, 742 (1988) (“Moreover, in markets characterized by rapid technological progress, competition often takes place on the basis of performance features and not price.”); David S. Evans & Richard Schmalensee, Some Economic Aspects of Antitrust Analysis in Dynamically Competitive Industries, in 2 Innovation Policy and The Economy 1, 3 (Adam B. Jaffe, et al., eds. 2002) (“The defining feature of new-economy industries is a competitive process dominated by efforts to create intellectual property through R&D, which often results in rapid and disruptive technological change.”).

[77] See generally William J. Baumol, John C. Panzar & Robert D. Willig, Contestable Markets and the Theory of Industry Structure (1982).

[78] Sidak & Teece, Dynamic Competition, supra note 71, at 585, 604.

[79] For a discussion of this principle and how it applies to broadband markets, see T. Randolph Beard, George S. Ford, Lawrence J. Spiwak, & Michael Stern, The Law and Economics of Municipal Broadband, 73 Fed. Comm’cns L.J. 1 (2020) [hereinafter, “Beard, Ford, Spiwak & Stern”].

[80] See Rabah Amir, Market Structure, Scale Economies and Industry Performance, CORE Discussion Paper No. 2003/65 (Sep. 1, 2003), https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=995721.

[81] See Demsetz, Why Regulate Utilities?, supra note 73; see also Sharat Ganapati, Growing Oligopolies, Prices, Output, and Productivity, Census Working Paper CES-WP-18-48 (Jan. 20, 2020), available at https://www.sganapati.com/files/Ganapati_2019_OligopoliesPricesQuantities_AEJmicro.pdf (noting that increased concentration results from a beneficial growth in firm size in productive industries that “expand real output and hold down prices, raising consumer welfare, while maintaining or reducing their workforces, lowering labor’s share of output.”)

[82] See generally J. Gregory Sidak & David J. Teece, Innovation Spillovers and The “Dirt Road” Fallacy: The Intellectual Bankruptcy of Banning Optional Transactions for Enhanced Delivery Over the Internet, 6 J. Comp. L. Econ. 521, 540 (2010) (Discussing the broad array of factors that must be taken into account in a dynamic analysis of the Internet and broadband service).

[83] Michelle Connolly & James E. Prieger, A Basic Analysis of Entry and Exit in the US Broadband Market, 2005-2008, Pepperdine University School of Public Policy Working Paper No. 42 (2013) at 4, https://digitalcommons.pepperdine.edu/sppworkingpapers/42 (published as Michelle Connolly & James E. Prieger, A Basic Analysis of Entry and Exit in the US Broadband Market, 2005-2008, 12 Rev. Network Econ. 229 (2013)).

[84] See generally Nicolai J. Foss & Peter G. Klein, Organizing Entrepreneurial Judgment (2012).

[85] See, e.g., Sidak & Teece, Dynamic Competition, supra note 71, at 615.

[86] Menko, supra note 46.

[87] See Daniel A. Lyons, Innovations in Mobile Broadband Pricing 3-4, Mercatus Center Working Paper No. 14-08 (Mar. 2014), available at https://www.mercatus.org/research/working-papers/innovations-mobile-broadband-pricing.

[88] Id.

[89] AT&T, Sponsored Data from AT&T (last accessed Dec. 12, 2023), https://www.att.com/att/sponsoreddata/en.

[90] T-Mobile, Unlimited Video Streaming with Binge On (last accessed Dec. 12, 2023), https://www.t-mobile.com/tv-streaming/binge-on.

[91] J. Gregory Sidak & David J. Teece, supra, note 82, at 532-33.

[92] See infra Section III.A.

[93] See, e.g., Herbert Hovenkamp, The Rule of Reason, 70 Fla. L. R. 81 (2018) (“Vertical restraints should be found unlawful only when they facilitate an output reduction that serves to increase prices in relation to costs. To that extent, every anticompetitive vertical restrain must contain at least an implicit horizontal element, whether it be collusion or exclusion. The vast majority of purely vertical agreements pose no such threat. These conclusions are largely borne out by the case law. Once the rule of reason is applied to a vertical practice, few instances of it are condemned.”)

[94] NPRM at ¶ 56.

[95] Id.

[96] Id.

[97] ICLE, Comments on Refreshing the Record in Restoring Internet Freedom and Lifeline Proceedings in Light of the D.C. Circuit’s Mozilla Decision, WC Docket Nos. 17-108, 17-287, 11-42 (Apr. 20, 2020), at 9, available at https://laweconcenter.org/wp-content/uploads/2020/04/icle_rifo_record_refresh_comments_final-20200420.pdf (“But the widely different regulatory philosophies underlying the Orders—that of the RIFO’s light-touch regulation under Title I compared to the OIO’s more interventionist regulation based on the uncertain whims of a changing political environment under Title II—strongly suggests different levels of regulatory certainty. And it is virtually inevitable that the greater regime uncertainty under Title II would contribute to a reduction in investment and/or its less efficient and effectively deployment. Such an effect is likely more attenuated than the acute, immediate response many seem to be looking for. But it may be no less real and no less important.”)

[98] Brendan Carr, Dissenting Statement of Commissioner Brendan Carr, Implementing the Infrastructure Investment and Jobs Act: Prevention and Elimination of Digital Discrimination, GN Docket No. 22-69, Report and Order and Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking (Nov. 15, 2023), https://docs.fcc.gov/public/attachments/FCC-23-100A3.pdf (Regarding digital discrimination rules, “The FCC reserves the right under this plan to regulate both ‘actions and omissions, whether recurring or a single instance.’ In other words, if you take any action, you may be liable, and if you do nothing, you may be liable. There is no path to complying with this standardless regime.”)

[99] See Edwin J. Elton & Martin J. Gruber, Modern Portfolio Theory and Investment Analysis (4th ed, 1991).

[100] Wolfgang Briglauer, Carlo Cambini, Klaus Gugler, & Volker Stocker, Net Neutrality and High-Speed Broadband Networks: Evidence from OECD Countries, 55 Eur. J. Law Econ. 533–571 (2023).

[101] Roslyn Layton & Mark Jamison, Net Neutrality in the USA During COVID-19, in Beyond the Pandemic? Exploring the Impact of COVID-19 on Telecommunications and the Internet, (Jason Whalley, Volker Stocker & William Lehr eds., 2023).

[102] NPRM at ¶ 56.

[103] NPRM at ¶ 157.

[104] FCC, Fact Sheet: FCC Chairwoman Rosenworcel Proposes to Restore Net Neutrality Rules (Sep. 26, 2023), available at https://docs.fcc.gov/public/attachments/DOC-397235A1.pdf.

[105] Rich Greenfield, Adding “Fast Lanes” Does Not Require Harming the Internet, Vox (May 14, 2014), https://www.vox.com/2014/5/14/11626812/adding-fast-lanes-does-not-require-harming-the-internet.

[106] Id.

[107] Catie Keck, A Look Under the Hood of the Most Successful Streaming Service on the Planet, The Verge (Nov. 17, 2021), https://www.theverge.com/22787426/netflix-cdn-open-connect.

[108] ICLE Comments., supra note 97 at 3-8. See also J. Gregory Sidak & David J. Teece, supra, note 82 at 533 (“Superior [quality of service] is a form of product differentiation, and it therefore increases welfare by increasing the production choices available to content and applications providers and the consumption choices available to end users. Finally, as in other two-sided platforms, optional business-to-business transactions for [quality of service] will allow broadband network operators to reduce subscription prices for broadband end users, promoting broadband adoption by end users, which will increase the value of the platform for all users.”).

[109] Axel Gautier & Robert Somogyi, Prioritization vs Zero-Rating: Discrimination on the Internet, 73 Int’l. J Ind. Org. 102662 (Dec. 2020).

[110] NPRM at ¶ 153.

[111] Id.

[112] Id. at ¶ 155.

[113] See Nilay Patel, Taylor Swift Fans Used Record Amounts of Data during the Eras Tour in North America, The Verge (Nov. 16, 2023), https://www.theverge.com/2023/11/16/23949041/taylor-swift-eras-tour-mobile-data-usage-att.

[114] Sandvine, Sandvine’s 2023 Global Internet Phenomena Report Shows 24% Jump in Video Traffic, with Netflix Volume Overtaking YouTube (Jan. 17, 2023), https://www.prnewswire.com/news-releases/sandvines-2023-global-internet-phenomena-report-shows-24-jump-in-video-traffic-with-netflix-volume-overtaking-youtube-301723445.html.

[115] Daeho Lee & Junseok Hwang, Network Neutrality and Difference in Efficiency Among Internet Application Service Providers: A Meta-Frontier Analysis, 35 Telecomm. Pol’y 764 (2011).

[116] Fangfan Li, Arian Akhavan Niaki, David Choffnes, Phillipa Gill, & Alan Mislove. A Large-Scale Analysis of Deployed Traffic Differentiation Practices, Association for Computing Machinery, Proceedings of the ACM Special Interest Group on Data Communication, SIGCOMM ’19 (2019), https://dl.acm.org/doi/pdf/10.1145/3341302.3342092.

[117] Christoph Bauner & Augusto Espin, Do Subscribers of Mobile Networks Care About Data Throttling?, 47 Telecom. Pol’y 102665 (Nov. 2023).

[118] Id. (“[U]sers may actually benefit from a modest degree of throttling as this preserves bandwidth and thus aides network stability and reliability. In other words, even if users get harmed by the direct effect of throttling (slower data transmission), the positive indirect effect (more reliable network) may outweigh this issue, so that users may prefer the throttled network. If this is the case, it would pose an additional argument against net neutrality regulation.”)

[119] Id.

[120] Hyun Ji Lee & Brian Whitacre, Estimating Willingness-to-Pay for Broadband Attributes Among Low-Income Consumers: Results From Two FCC Lifeline Pilot Projects, 41 Telecomm. Pol’y. 769 (Oct. 2017).

[121] Johnny Kampis, Johnny Kampis: FCC Push To Eliminate Data Caps Could Increase Broadband Rates For Many Users, Broadband Breakfast (Sep. 28, 2023), https://broadbandbreakfast.com/2023/09/johnny-kampis-fcc-push-to-eliminate-data-caps-could-increase-broadband-rates-for-many-users.

[122] Peter Christiansen, Survey Finds Nearly Half of America Unaware of Internet Data Cap Limits, HighSpeedInternet.com (Feb. 25, 2021), https://www.highspeedinternet.com/resources/data-caps-survey.

[123] See Working Group on Economic Impacts of Open Internet Frameworks, Policy Issues in Data Caps and Usage-Based Pricing, Open Internet Advisory Committee (Jul. 9, 2013), available at https://transition.fcc.gov/cgb/oiac/Economic-Impacts.pdf.

[124] See id. at 14-16.

[125] 2015 Order at ¶¶ 151-153.

[126] Id.

[127] Guz Hurwitz, The Not Neutrality of Tech Reporting: Discussing the Economics of Lifting Data Caps During a Stay-at-Home Crisis, Truth on the Market (Mar. 20, 2020), https://truthonthemarket.com/2020/03/20/the-not-neutrality-of-tech-reporting-discussing-the-economics-of-lifting-data-caps-during-a-stay-at-home-crisis.

[128] Hyun Ji Lee & Brian Whitacre, Estimating Willingness-to-Pay for Broadband Attributes among Low-Income Consumers: Results from Two FCC Lifeline Pilot Projects, 41 Telecomm. Pol’y. 769 (2017).

[129] See Scott Jordan, A Critical Survey of the Literature on Broadband Data Caps, 41 Telecomm. Pol’y 813 (2017).

[130] NPRM at ¶ 137.

[131] 2015 Order at ¶¶ 78-101; see also In the Matter of Protecting & Promoting the Open Internet, Dissenting Statement of Commissioner Michael O’Rielly, 30 F.C.C. Rcd. 5601, 5987 (2015) (“Even after enduring three weeks of spin, it is hard for me to believe that the Commission is establishing an entire Title II/net neutrality regime to protect against hypothetical harms. There is not a shred of evidence that any aspect of this structure is necessary. The D.C. Circuit called the prior, scaled-down version a “prophylactic” approach. I call it guilt by imagination.”).

[132] 2018 Order at ¶¶ 109-139.

[133] 2018 Order at ¶ 143.

[134] Stephen G. Breyer, Antitrust, Deregulation, and the Newly Liberated Marketplace, 75 Cal. L. Rev. 1005, 1007 (1987).

[135] Id.

[136] 2018 Order at ¶ 123. See also Joshua D. Wright & Thomas W. Hazlett, The Effect of Regulation on Broadband Markets: Evaluating the Empirical Evidence in the FCC’s 2015 “Open Internet” Order, 50 Rev. Indus. Org. 487, 489 (2017) (Network neutrality rules address conduct that “[i]f undertaken for anti-competitive purpose and achieving anti-competitive effect, [] would be deemed vertical foreclosure in economics (or under antitrust law).”). See also 2015 Order at ¶ 79 & note 123 (discussing past instances of alleged ISP misconduct that amounted to “limit[ations on] openness,” all of which were cognizable under the antitrust laws).

[137] 2015 Order at ¶ 63.

[138] Id. at ¶ 64.

[139] Id. at  ¶ 275.

[140] Id. at ¶ 140.

[141] See Patrick Rey & Jean Tirole, A Primer on Foreclosure, in III Handbook of Indus. Org. 2145 (Mark Armstrong & Rob Porter eds., 2007).

[142] NPRM at ¶ 23.

[143] See Rey & Tirole, A Primer on Foreclosure, supra note 140.

[144] See Francine Lafontaine & Margaret Slade, Vertical Integration and Firm Boundaries: The Evidence, 45 J. Econ. Lit. 629 (2007) (documenting the economic evidence showing that such vertical relationships are more likely to be competitively beneficial or benign than to raise serious threats of foreclosure).

[145] See Leegin Creative Leather Prods., Inc. v. PSKS, Inc., 551 U.S. 877, 886-87 (2007) (holding that the per se rule should be applied “only after courts have had considerable experience with the type of restraint at issue” and “only if courts can predict with confidence that [the restraint] would be invalidated in all or almost all instances under the rule of reason” because it “‘lack[s] . . . any redeeming virtue.’” (citation omitted)).

[146] See D. Daniel Sokol, The Transformation of Vertical Restraints: Per Se Illegality, the Rule of Reason, and Per Se Legality, 79 Antitrust L.J. 1003, 1004 (2014) (“[T]he shift in the antitrust rules applied to [vertical restraints] has not been from per se illegality to the rule of reason, but has been a more dramatic shift from per se illegality to presumptive legality under the rule of reason”).

[147] NPRM at ¶ 136 (“The Commission’s transparency rule requires ISPs to publicly disclose the network practices, performance characteristics, and commercial terms of the BIAS they offer, including disclosure of any blocking, throttling, and affiliated or paid prioritization practices.”).

[148] See, e.g. Geoffrey A. Manne, The Hydraulic Theory of Disclosure Regulation and Other Costs of Disclosure, 58 Ala. L. Rev. 473 (2007).

[149] NPRM at ¶¶ 172-175.

[150] 47 U.S.C. § 201(b).

[151] Eric Fruits, Everyone Discriminates Under the FCC’s Proposed New Rules, Truth on the Market (Oct. 30, 2023), https://truthonthemarket.com/2023/10/30/everyone-discriminates-under-the-fccs-proposed-new-rules.

[152] NPRM at ¶ 175.

[153] See NPRM at ¶¶ 80-83.

[154] King v. Burwell, 576 U.S. 473, 486 (2015) (quoting Utility Air Regulatory Group v. EPA, 573 U.S. 302, 324 (2014)).

[155] 141 S. Ct. 2485 (2021).

[156] Id. at 2489.

[157] Id.

[158] Id.

[159] 142 S. Ct. 661 (2022).

[160] Id. at 665.

[161] Id.

[162] Id.

[163] Id. at 669.

[164] 142 S. Ct. 2587 (2022).

[165] See id. at 2607-09.

[166] Id. at 2609.

[167] See id. at 2612.

[168] See id. at 2614.

[169] See id. at 2615-17.

[170] NFIB, 142 S. Ct. at 668.

[171] See, e.g., 2022 Broadband Capex Report, USTelecom (Sep. 8, 2023), https://ustelecom.org/research/2022-broadband-capex (“America’s broadband industry invested a record $102.4 billion in U.S. communications infrastructure in 2022, reflecting broadband providers’ determination to help achieve the national objective of affordable, reliable high-speed connectivity for all. The annual figure represents a 21-year high for investment from the communications sector and a 19% year-over-year increase.”).

[172] See NPRM at ¶ 1 (“Congress responded by investing tens of billions of dollars into building out broadband Internet networks and making access more affordable and equitable, culminating in the generational investment of $65 billion in the Infrastructure Investment and Jobs Act.”); 47 U.S.C. § 1701(1) (“[A]ccess to affordable, reliable, high-speed broadband is essential to full participation in modern life in the United States.”). See also 47 U.S.C. §§ 1722(1)(A)-(B) (“[A] broadband connection and digital literacy are increasingly critical to how individuals (A) participate in society, economy and civic institutions of the United States;” and “(B) access health care and essential services, obtain education, and build careers.”)

[173] See supra Part II.C.

[174] US Telecom v. FCC, 855 F.3d 381, 422 (D.C. Cir. 2016) (Kavanaugh, J., dissenting from denial of rehearing en banc).

[175] See NPRM at ¶¶ 103-113. See also FCC Fact Sheet, Safeguarding and Securing the Open Internet (Sept. 28, 2023) (“Propose to forbear from 26 Title II provisions, and clarify that the Commission will not regulate rates or require network unbundling.”).

[176] 573 US. 302, 328 (2014) (“We reaffirm the core administrative-law principle that an agency may not rewrite clear statutory terms to suit its own sense of how the statute should operate.”).

[177] See id. at 326 (“The Tailoring Rule is not just an announcement of EPA’s refusal to enforce the statutory permitting requirements; it purports to alter those requirements and to establish with the force of law that otherwise-prohibited conduct will not violate the Act. This alteration of the statutory requirements was crucial to EPA’s “tailoring” efforts. Without it, small entities with the potential to emit greenhouse gases in amounts exceeding the statutory thresholds would have remained subject to citizen suits—authorized by the Act.”).

[178] Id. at 325.

[179] Id. at 328.

[180] See US Telecom, 855 F.3d at 383-85 (Srinivasan, J. & Tatel, J., concurring in denial from rehearing en banc).

[181] See id. at 385 (“In Brand X, the Supreme Court definitively — and authoritatively, for our purposes as an inferior court — answered that question yes.”).

[182] See Brand X, 545 U.S. at 989 (“[T]he statute fails unambiguously to classify the telecommunications component of cable modem service as a distinct offering.”).

[183] See id. at 1005-14 (Scalia, J., dissenting).

[184] See US Telecom v. FCC, 825 F.3d 674 (D.C. Cir. 2016).

[185] See Mozilla Corp v. FCC, 940 F.3d 1 (D.C. Cir. 2019).

Continue reading
Telecommunications & Regulated Utilities

ICLE Amicus to the 1st Circuit in US v American Airlines

Amicus Brief INTERESTS OF AMICUS CURIAE[1] The International Center for Law & Economics (“ICLE”) is a nonprofit, non-partisan global research and policy center aimed at building the . . .

INTERESTS OF AMICUS CURIAE[1]

The International Center for Law & Economics (“ICLE”) is a nonprofit, non-partisan global research and policy center aimed at building the intellectual foundations for sensible, economically grounded policy.  ICLE promotes the use of law & economics methodologies to inform public policy debates and has longstanding expertise in the evaluation of antitrust law and policy.  ICLE has an interest in ensuring that antitrust promotes the public interest by remaining grounded in sensible legal rules informed by sound economic analysis.

Amici also include five scholars of antitrust, law, and economics.  Their names, titles, and academic affiliations are listed in the Addendum.  All have longstanding expertise in, and have done extensive research in, the fields of antitrust law and economics.

Amici have an interest in ensuring that antitrust law remains grounded in clear rules, established precedent, record evidence, and sound economic analysis.  The district court’s decision erodes such foundations by focusing on the number of competitors rather than the impact on competition.  Overall, amici have a profound interest in an intellectually coherent antitrust policy focused upon safeguarding competition itself.[2]

INTRODUCTION

Over a century ago, the Supreme Court wisely recognized that “[t]he true test of legality is whether the restraint imposed is such as merely regulates and perhaps thereby promotes competition or whether it is such as may suppress or even destroy competition.”  Bd. of Trade of Chi. v. United States, 246 U.S. 231, 238 (1918).  Echoing that foundational insight, the district court opinion (the “Opinion”) opened by posing, “This case turns on what ‘competition’ means,” only to proceed by applying a flawed analysis of the Sherman Act and governing authority.  ADD10.[3]

The Opinion launches its scrutiny of the NEA by positing as an aim of federal antitrust law the fostering of “participation by a diverse array of competitors.”  Id.  But the Opinion provides no citation or clarification for this proposition, which is at odds with the Opinion’s later recognition that the antitrust laws are concerned with competition, not the specific competitors.  See ADD68 (“[T]he Sherman Act ‘unequivocally’ establishes a policy favoring and protecting competition.”).  The Opinion further leaves out that “consumer welfare” is the touchstone of antitrust analysis, not the health of any particular array of competitors.  See Concord v. Bos. Edison Co., 915 F.2d 17, 21 (1st Cir. 1990); see also Apex Hosiery Co. v. Leader, 310 U.S. 469, 500-01 (1940).

This amicus brief addresses three fundamental failings of the Opinion, each of which requires reversal:  First, the Opinion equates the simple reduction in the number of competitors by one with a fatal (and illegal) reduction in competition.  Second, the Opinion analyzes the Northeast Alliance (“NEA”), involving specific operations focused on New York, New Jersey, and Boston, as a horizontal merger.  Finally, the Opinion subjected the NEA to an inappropriate, truncated review rather than a full rule of reason analysis.

This Court should reverse the district court’s faulty application of key competition law principles.  A counting exercise tallying autonomous rivals is not what matters under the Sherman Act; rather, the focus is on an economic process that assesses impacts on “material progress.”  N. Pac. Ry. Co. v. United States, 356 U.S. 1, 4 (1958).  Getting the competition definition right matters greatly, as everything else follows from that foundation.  An opportunity to reiterate and cement proper understandings seldom appears; seizing this occasion is imperative.

ARGUMENT

I.              Alliances Are Not of Themselves Synonymous With Anticompetitive Harm

Inherent in any joint venture is some degree of restraint on the direct competition between the joint venture parties themselves as they create a single venture with the goal of greater competition against other competitors and better results for consumers, usually through increased output or improved products or services at competitive prices.  See Fed. Trade Comm’n & Dep’t of Justice, Antitrust Guidelines for Collaboration Among Competitors (April 2000) at 2 (hereinafter “Collaboration Guidelines”) (“[P]articipants in a collaboration typically remain potential competitors, even if they are not actual competitors for certain purposes (e.g., R&D) during the collaboration.”) (emphasis added).  As Appellant’s brief summarizes, through the NEA, the two airlines here achieved exactly those goals of increasing output and enhancing the quality of services without any demonstrated price increases, such that consumer welfare was greatly enhanced in a procompetitive fashion, notwithstanding that on certain routes they were no longer direct competitors.  App. Br. 6-14.

Throughout, the Opinion’s analysis is skewed by the notion that “the number of competitors has literally decreased by one,” which the Opinion treats as an intrinsically intolerable “assault on competition.”  ADD43, ADD92.  Simply put, the Opinion improperly conflates “competition” with “number of competitors,” effectively ignoring established legal authority and economics confirming that safeguarding the overall competitive process is the paramount means for maximizing consumer welfare—not preserving an existing market structure with a particular number of rivals.  As this Court has long held:

[T]he Court recognizes that the antitrust laws exist to protect the competitive process itself, not individual firms. [citations omitted] And the antitrust laws protect the competitive process in order to help individual consumers by bringing them the benefits of low, economically efficient prices, efficient production methods, and innovation.

Grappone, Inc. v. Subaru of New Eng., 858 F.2d 792, 794 (1st Cir. 1988) (Breyer, J.) (collecting cases, including Brown Shoe and Broad. Music, Inc.).

The Opinion’s treatment of the mere reduction of competitors by one on NEA routes in favor of a limited, regional collaboration as an “assault on competition” infected all of the Opinion’s analysis of the impact of the collaboration, and this error independently requires reversal.  Economics and binding precedent caution that static market shares and a mere reduction in the number of competitors do not constitute a basis for condemnation absent proof that prices increased, output decreased, or quality suffered.  See, e.g., Ohio v. Am. Express Co., 138 S. Ct. 2274, 2288 (2018) (“This Court will ‘not infer competitive injury from price and output data absent some evidence that tends to prove that output was restricted or prices were above a competitive level.’” (citing Brooke Grp. Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 509 U.S. 209, 237 (1993))).

A.            Joint Ventures Depend on Collaboration to Increase Consumer Welfare

The Opinion concludes that there will be future competitive harm based on a minor reduction in competitors without requiring a showing—despite the “tidal wave of evidence” (ADD12)—that output diminished or prices increased.  Such a showing is an essential prerequisite to render concentration economically meaningful.  See Am. Express Co., 138 S. Ct. 2274 at 2284 (“Direct evidence of anticompetitive effects would be ‘proof of actual detrimental effects’ . . . such as reduced output, increased prices, or decreased quality . . .”) (citations omitted).  The Opinion is rife with statements demonstrating that the loss of one competitor on regional routes was dispositive here—the ultimate thumb on the scales:

  • First, the NEA has eliminated the once vigorous competition between two of the four largest domestic carriers in the northeast . . .” ADD76 (underlining in original).
  • “This, in and of itself, is a fundamental assault on competition and an actual harm the Sherman Act is designed to prevent . . . .” ADD77.
  • “Eliminating potential competition is, by definition, anticompetitive.” Id. (quoting Impax out of context).
  • “As explained already, the overarching purpose of the NEA is anticompetitive. Through the NEA, American and JetBlue cease to compete and, instead, operate as a single carrier in the northeast.  That it is the core of the relationship, and it is a naked assault on competition.”

Such quick and premature condemnation of business collaborations on flimsy theories of concentration and alleged loss of independent decision-makers contravenes the precedent of this Court and of other circuit courts.  See, e.g., Augusta News Co. v. Hudson News Co., 269 F.3d 41, 47 (1st Cir. 2001) (under rule of reason, “adverse effects on consumer welfare are an important part of the equation” and that “it is hard to imagine a rule of reason violation absent a potential threat to the public”); Marucci Sports, L.L.C. v. Nat’l Collegiate Athletic Ass’n, 751 F.3d 368, 377 (5th Cir. 2014) (“A restraint should not be deemed unlawful, even if it eliminates a competitor from the market, so long as sufficient competitors remain to ensure that competitive prices, quality, and service persist.”) (emphasis added); Rebel Oil Co. v. Atl. Richfield Co., 51 F.3d 1421, 1433 (9th Cir. 1995) (“reduction of competition does not invoke the Sherman Act until it harms consumer welfare”).  Such summary disposition virtually assures penalizing or prohibiting beneficial alliances that advantage consumers and enhance consumer choice.

As the Collaboration Guidelines have recognized for over two decades, “collaborations often are not only benign, but procompetitive.”  Collaboration Guidelines at 2.  Further, the Collaboration Guidelines emphasize, in the first sentence of the preamble, that “[i]n order to compete in modern markets, competitors sometimes need to collaborate.”  Id. at 1; see also id. at 6 (“A collaboration may allow its participants to better use existing assets, or may provide incentives for them to make output-enhancing investments that would not occur absent the collaboration.  The potential efficiencies from competitor collaborations may be achieved through a variety of contractual arrangements including joint ventures . . . .”).  Notably, the Opinion largely ignores the Collaboration Guidelines and their explication of the benefits of joint ventures, citing them only in passing as a “see also” for the proposition that “some collaborations” should be treated like “complete or partial merger[s].”  ADD69.  In the Opinion’s take on the Collaboration Guidelines, the tail wags the dog.

The Collaboration Guidelines are consistent with established Supreme Court precedent recognizing the common benefits of competitor collaborations, even as they require specific, limited collaboration rather than competition between enterprises that are otherwise competitors.  See Nat’l Collegiate Athletic Ass’n v. Alston, 141 S. Ct. 2141, 2155 (2021) (“[M]any joint ventures are calculated to enable firms to do something more cheaply or better than they did it before.  And the fact that joint ventures can have such procompetitive benefits surely stands as a caution against condemning their arrangements too reflexively.”) (citation omitted); Texaco Inc. v. Dagher, 547 U.S. 1, 6 n.1 (2006) (recognizing the “economic justifications,” “numerous synergies and cost efficiencies” resulting from a joint venture).

And this Court has recognized that “bona fide joint ventures”—like the U.S.-Department-of-Transportation-approved NEA here—allow two competitors to pool their resources to “provide offerings” that neither “could easily provide by itself.”  Augusta News, 269 F.3d at 48.  This Court’s articulation in Augusta News of the joint venture providing offerings that neither partner “could easily provide by itself” is a more permissive standard than the Opinion’s jaded view requiring a joint venture to pool “complementary assets.”  ADD93; see also id. (“[T]he defendants have not established their pooled assets are ‘complementary,’ . . . such that they enable the defendants to create an innovative product”).

The Opinion seems to hold that for a joint venture to overcome its intrinsic “assault on competition” it must produce something novel, as opposed to enhancing competition (through better service or greater output) against other competitors.  Rejecting the NEA’s plaintiffs-conceded, pro-competitive benefits, the Opinion notes that “other firms (Delta and United), acting independently, already offer ‘products’ comparable to the one they claim their collaboration will enable . . .”   ADD92; see also id. (“Collaboration between the defendants is not required in order to create a new product or market that could not otherwise exist.”).  But under the Sherman Act and the Collaboration Guidelines, horizontal joint ventures are not held to a “Eureka!” novel-creation standard.

Notably, the DOJ’s Collaboration Guidelines expressly contemplate a similar asset-collaboration.  Collaboration Guidelines at 31.  In Example 6, two major software producers—neither of which was a “major competitor” of the two dominant firms in the word-processing software market—joined forces “to develop a markedly better word-processing program together than either [could] produce on its own.”  Id.  This combination was “an efficiency-enhancing integration of economic activity that promotes procompetitive benefits.”  Id.  So too with the NEA.

Indeed, if combinations were held to a novel-creation standard, the joint venture analyzed by the Supreme Court in Dagher for refining and selling gasoline in the western states (where Texaco and Shell previously competed) could not have survived scrutiny.  547 U.S. at 4 (describing Texaco and Shell Oil joint venture agreement as “ending competition between the two companies in the domestic refining and marketing of gasoline”).  The Supreme Court not only accepted as lawful a joint venture between two companies that were previously direct competitors (547 U.S. at 4 n1.), but also ruled that even the joint venture’s price-setting was not subject to per se treatment, citing the combination’s overall procompetitive benefits.  Id. at 8 (“[T]he pricing decisions of a legitimate joint venture do not fall within the narrow category of activity that is per se unlawful.”).

In insisting that American and JetBlue create something novel, i.e., not offered by competitors like Delta or United, or contribute only “complementary” assets to the NEA to do something each could not have done on its own, the Opinion is unsupported by legal authority and should be reversed.

B.            The Proof Is in the Pudding, Not in the Number of Rivals

By enshrining the mere independence of competitors above actual competitive performance and by failing to examine the NEA’s actual consumer welfare effects, the Opinion unjustifiably penalized the NEA’s consumer-enhancing aspects.  See ADD94-ADD95 (recognizing that NEA allowed for certain benefits, such as better route scheduling, but faulting parties because such benefits occurred through parties “cooperat[ing] in ways that horizontal competitors normally would not”).  Indeed, the Opinion sharply (and repeatedly) minimizes or ignores altogether tangible evidence regarding NEA-generated network expansions, connectivity optimization, increased service frequencies to underserved airports, enhanced schedule optionality, reciprocal loyalty benefits, and codesharing conveniences enhancing routing choices.  See ADD30 (noting, without further acknowledging, that the NEA-generated services and benefits “extend to most of the carriers’ flights to and from Logan, JFK, LaGuardia, and Newark”).

Moving beyond the reduction of competitors on certain routes, the proof was in the pudding of the extensive trial record.  The evidence demonstrated that the NEA (1) increased capacity by more than 200% at NEA airports (2-JA1293),
(2) offered almost 50 new nonstop routes, (3) increased their frequency on over 130 routes, and (4) increased their capacity on 45 New York City flights (2-JA1367-68).  In fact, the record shows that the NEA well-exceeded the growth commitments for 2022 and beyond to which American and JetBlue had agreed with the Department of Transportation to obtain its blessing.  See 2-JA821.

But the Opinion rejected all of these procompetitive, consumer-friendly benefits because, in its view, they were the result of the “unlawful” reduction of competitors by one.  The Opinion’s rejection of these benefits was erroneous and in contravention to settled authority.  See United States v. Interstate Commerce Comm’n, 396 U.S. 491, 523 (1970) (affirming dismissal of complaint challenging railroad merger where “the long-run effect of the merger would be to benefit communities . . . , and that the brief and transitory dislocations the merger would occasion were not sufficient to outweigh the merger’s benefits”); Penn-Central Merger & N & W Inclusion Cases, 389 U.S. 486, 500-01 (1968) (affirming dismissal of competitor suits opposing merger, noting that evidence showed merger would benefit general public, allowing “the unified company to ‘accelerate investments in transportation property and continually modernize plant and equipment . . . and provide more and better service’”).  The Opinion’s singular focus was also contrary to the Collaboration Guidelines, which state that, even in cases where the number of competitors drops, “the evaluating Agency would take account of . . . any procompetitive benefits . . .  under present circumstances, along with other factors.”  Collaboration Guidelines at 29-30.

This Court has the opportunity to underscore that, under federal antitrust law, efficiency assertions deserve a balanced assessment in calculating net effects, rather than the cramped disposal through summary scapegoating of innovative integration models that occurred in the Opinion (ADD88-ADD99).  See Cont’l T.V. v. GTE Sylvania, 433 U.S. 36, 49 (1977) (under rule of reason, “the fact-finder weighs all of the circumstances of a case in deciding whether a restrictive practice should be prohibited as imposing an unreasonable restraint on competition”); see also Am. Express Co., 138 S. Ct. at 2290 (affirming judgment for defendants where plaintiffs could not show anticompetitive effects and thus “failed to satisfy the first step of the rule of reason”); Leegin Creative Leather Prods. v. PSKS, Inc., 551 U.S. 877, 886 (2007) (“In its design and function the rule [of reason] distinguishes between restraints with anticompetitive effect that are harmful to the consumer and restraints stimulating competition that are in the consumer’s best interest.”).

II.           THE DISTRICT COURT ERRED BY TREATING THE NEA’S LIMITED REGIONAL COLLABORATION LIKE A FULL-ON HORIZONTAL MERGER

One of the core flaws permeating the Opinion’s analysis is its effective adoption of the plaintiffs’ view that the NEA should be analyzed as a merger— comprehensively eliminating the rivalry between American and JetBlue—instead of a joint ventureSee ADD37 (“Nevertheless, as implemented by the parties, its effects resemble those of a merger of the parties’ operations within the northeast . . . .”), ADD38 (“[T]hey function like a single airline in the NEA region, as much as possible.”), ADD40 (faulting airlines for adjusting certain nationwide priorities, including American’s deprioritizing Philadelphia for New York and JetBlue pausing plans for growth in Fort Lauderdale); ADD46 (faulting JetBlue for supposedly increasing its operating costs).  But contrary to the Opinion’s suggestion (ADD69), not even the Collaboration Guidelines support the Opinion’s analysis.  See, e.g., Collaboration Guidelines at 5 (“The competitive effects from competitor collaborations may differ from those of mergers due to a number of factors.”).

A.            The NEA Is a Limited Regional Joint Venture That Preserved Each Participant’s Pricing Decisions Even Within the Region

The Opinion’s merger-like view of the regional collaboration ignored or downplayed important distinctions between the NEA’s operation and those of a national merger of competitors, not the least of which was that American and JetBlue maintained independent pricing.  See ADD77 (“American and JetBlue do not discuss the fares they will set . . . .”).  More generally, the NEA is structured like the archetypical limited joint venture, including (1) a fixed scope and duration, (2) no asset transfer, (3) no price coordination, and (4) separate management and business strategies, even in the NEA’s market.  See ADD27-ADD37; see also id. at ADD37 (“Both [American and JetBlue] have operations that fall beyond the NEA’s reach, and the agreement does not formally embody a complete combination of the partners’ operations even within the NEA region.”).

Critically, each airline retained control over routes not covered, with flexibility in responding through tactical fare adjustments even within the Northeast region.  See 1-JA572 (“Q. And do you ever discuss capacity outside the Northeast Alliance with American.  A. Absolutely not.”)); ADD30 (noting that each partner “will continue to make independent decisions regarding pricing, capacity, and network management”).

These characteristics, among many others, make it inappropriate and legal error for the Opinion to analyze the NEA effectively as a horizontal merger.  See, e.g., Addamax Corp. v. Open Software Found., 152 F.3d 48, 52 (1st Cir. 1998) (when “there is patently a potential for a productive contribution to the economy, [] conduct that is strictly ancillary to this productive effort (e.g., the joint venture’s decision as to the price at which it will purchase inputs) is evaluated under the rule of reason”).

B.            Joint Ventures Offer Unique, Pro-Competitive Benefits

The Opinion’s treatment of the NEA as a merger and not a limited joint venture was error, particularly given that joint ventures such as the NEA offer unique benefits, often superior both to firms operating independently and to a merger.  Joint ventures and mergers differ substantially in structure, scope, competitive impacts, and efficiency gains.  Whereas mergers combine entire firms under common ownership and control, joint ventures allow companies to “pool a portion of their resources within a common legal organization” through partnership, while still operating as independent entities.  See Bruce Kogut, Joint Ventures: Theoretical and Empirical Perspectives, 9 Strategic Mgmt. J. 319, 319 (1988).  The remaining independence is what distinguishes joint ventures from mergers.  See Herbert Hovenkamp & Phillip E. Areeda, Antitrust Law: An Analysis of Antitrust Principles and Their Application, ¶2100c (5th ed. 2022) (“[J]oint ventures are calculated to enable firms to do something more cheaply or better than they did it before” making them “presumably efficient.”).  This allows greater flexibility to renegotiate or unwind collaborations without the permanence of an acquisition.  Joint ventures allow valuable collaboration and access to partners’ knowledge without requiring a permanent, fully integrated merger that may be costly to reverse.  See Srinivasan Balakrishnan & Mitchell P. Koza, Information Asymmetry, Adverse Selection and Joint-Ventures: Theory and Evidence, 20 J. Econ. Behav. & Org. 99, 103 (1993).

Joint ventures also frequently have a narrower objective than mergers, focusing on specific areas rather than seeking complete integration across all business functions.  In the case of the NEA, the focus areas were increased service frequencies to underserved airports, enhanced schedule optionality in the face of tight FAA regulations and limited gate availability, and reciprocal loyalty benefits in one geographic location.  ADD30.  And by maintaining separate pricing decisions (ADD77), the NEA could realize productive efficiencies for the parties and consumers from collaboration, asset pooling, and knowledge sharing without the potential anticompetitive effects of an outright merger.

Economic theory and experience suggest that joint ventures pose fewer anticompetitive concerns because they do not reduce the number of independent competitors in a market, contrary to the Opinion.  For example, Gugler & Siebert find that mergers and joint ventures in the semiconductor industry increased participating firms’ market shares on average, identifying net efficiency gains allowing the participating firms to win more of the market.  As such, joint ventures represent desirable alternatives to mergers from a consumer welfare perspective.  See Klaus Gugler & Ralph Siebert, Market Power Versus Efficiency Effects of Mergers and Research Joint Ventures: Evidence from the Semiconductor Industry, 89 Rev. Econ. Stat. 645, 646 (2007).  By maintaining separate ownership and pricing control, joint ventures allow firms to pool assets and improve productivity while preserving more market participants.  Thus, the structure enables collaboration without the consolidated market power of an outright merger.  This further highlights the key differences between joint ventures and full integration through acquisition, which the Opinion misses entirely.

III.        JOINT VENTURES LIKE THE NEA REQUIRE FULL RULE OF REASON ANALYSIS—NOT QUICK LOOK OR SHORT CUTS

Finally, the Opinion incorrectly concluded that agreements between competitors that reduce the number of market participants was “especially harmful.”  ADD83.  The Opinion then subjected the NEA to an inappropriate truncated style of review, tantamount to the “quick look” approach the Opinion claimed to recognize was not in fact permitted here.  See ADD75.  Rather than conduct a full rule of reason analysis, the Opinion holds that as to the NEA, “no deep and searching analysis is required in order to discern its unlawfulness.”   ADD76 (going so far as to state that “the NEA is situated ‘at one end of the competitive spectrum’”)); see also ADD87 (indicating that NEA could be deemed unreasonable “in the twinkling of an eye”).  Nowhere does the Opinion conduct the required weighing of the competitive benefits identified by Appellant against presumed, long-run risks alleged by the plaintiffs.  See Dagher, 547 U.S. at 5 (rule of reason “presumptively applies” absent per se violations).

A.            In Dagher, the Supreme Court Confirmed the Presumptive Application of Rule of Reason to Joint Ventures

In Dagher—under similar facts to here—the Supreme Court overturned a decision by the Ninth Circuit condemning the practices of a gasoline refining and sales joint venture, Equilon Enterprises, set up by oil giants Shell and Texaco in the western region of the United States.  As the Supreme Court explained, the district court had rejected plaintiffs’ request to apply quick look, and at summary judgment had upheld the joint venture’s challenged activities procompetitive.  547 U.S. at 4.  The Ninth Circuit reversed, characterizing the position of the petitioners as seeking an exception to the per se prohibition on price fixing.  Id. 

In confirming that the rule of reason applied to the joint venture’s challenged activities, the Supreme Court unambiguously stated that “this Court presumptively applies rule of reason analysis, under which antitrust plaintiffs must demonstrate that a particular contract or combination is in fact unreasonable and anticompetitive before it will be found unlawful.”  Id. at 5 (emphasis added).  The Court specifically rejected applying per se or anything other than full, rule of reason scrutiny to Equilon, effectively rejecting any sort of Topco-like suggestion that there should be “an especially heavy burden on the collaborators to justify what otherwise would be obviously unlawful collusion.”  ADD14; see also Dagher, 547 U.S. at 5 (“These cases do not present such an agreement, however, because Texaco and Shell oil did not compete with one another in the relevant market—namely, the sale of gasoline to service stations in the western United States—but instead participated in the market jointly through their investments in Equilon.”).  The Court was also clear that any challenge to the formation of the joint venture itself would need to prove that “its creation was anticompetitive under the rule of reason.”  Id. at 6 n.1.

Here, the district court transgressed the fundamentals of Dagher and other Supreme Court authority on joint ventures by dispensing with the NEA based on a truncated analysis.  See Alston, 141 S. Ct. at 2155 (rejecting a “quick look” analysis for the challenged joint venture and affirming that “[m]ost restraints challenged under the Sherman Act—including most joint venture restrictions—are subject to the rule of reason”); Broad. Music, Inc. v. Columbia Broad. Sys., Inc., 441 U.S. 1, 23 (1979) (per se rule does not apply to all agreements between competitors, “[j]oint ventures and other cooperative arrangements are also not usually unlawful”).  Only by insisting on disciplined economic welfare-based analysis—not conclusory structural shortcuts—can this Court correct methodological shortfalls and realign doctrine in this Circuit to safeguard innovative joint ventures that enhance consumer choice and welfare.

B.            “Quick Look” Analysis Applies Only to a Narrow Category Of Agreements That Does Not Include the NEA

Beyond Dagher and other Supreme Court authority, since at least 1978 the Supreme Court, in decisions like Professional Engineers, has carefully confined the application of truncated “quick look” analysis.  “Quick look” analysis is reserved for that limited category of restraints where genuinely anticompetitive effects are so intuitively obvious that “no elaborate industry analysis is required to demonstrate the anticompetitive character of such an agreement.”  Nat’l Soc’y of Prof’l Eng’rs. v. United States, 435 U.S. 679, 692 (1978); see Alston, 141 S. Ct. at 2155 (noting that joint venture restrictions are subject to rule of reason).

Such cases typically feature overt, horizontal output restrictions, price agreements, or naked market divisions devoid of cognizable efficiencies.  In Professional Engineers, it was a bidding agreement that “operates as an absolute ban on competitive bidding.”  435 U.S. at 692.  The NEA—with its established output expansion and consumer choices—falls far outside such restrictions.

And it remains equally settled that where defendants provide plausible justifications that a practice enhances overall efficiency and makes markets more competitive, per se and quick look approaches must end and full rule of reason procedures must begin.  As the Supreme Court has explained, “per se rules are appropriate only for ‘conduct that is manifestly anticompetitive,’ . . . that is, conduct ‘that would always or almost always tend to restrict competition and decrease output.’”  Bus. Elecs. v. Sharp Elecs., 485 U.S. 717, 723 (1988) (internal citation omitted) (citing cases); see also Fed. Trade Comm’n v. Ind. Fed’n of Dentists, 476 U.S. 447, 458-59 (1986) (“[W]e have been slow . . . to extend per se analysis to restraints imposed in the context of business relationships where the economic impact of certain practices is not immediately obvious.”).  Numerous decisions underscore that quick-look bypassing of comprehensive balancing is permissible only for “agreements whose nature and necessary effect are so plainly anticompetitive that no elaborate study of the industry is needed.”  Nat’l Soc’y of Prof’l Eng’rs, 435 U.S. at 692.

C.            The Opinion Erred by Not Applying Full Rule of Reason Review

While the Opinion stated it “declines to apply per se analysis,” the Opinion intimates that its approach was effectively per seSee ADD83 (“deliberate market allocation inherent in the NEA is strong evidence of its actual anticompetitive effect”).  Given the wide gap between the NEA and per se agreements, the Opinion was without legal basis “to conclude that the NEA is situated ‘at [one] end[] of the competitive spectrum” such “that no deep and searching analysis is required in order to discern its unlawfulness.”   ADD76 (citing Alston, 141 S. Ct. at 2155).

Instead, when business collaborations between competitors incorporate sets of tradeoffs, immediate condemnation remains wholly improper without balanced vetting.  The default rule of Dagher requires a full rule of reason analysis, given intrinsic efficiency possibilities.  547 U.S. at 5.  Reasoned scrutiny becomes imperative for collaborations with facially plausible claims of providing new products, penetrating untreated geographic segments, optimizing scheduling, capturing scale economies, or administering loyalty programs more seamlessly than individual participants could achieve alone.  See ADD30 (noting such NEA arrangements).

The airline context poses heightened calls for caution before neutralizing innovative business formats with a quick look, because alliances there can generate acknowledged consumer value through coordinated flight timing, codesharing, reciprocal lounge privileges, baggage handling, and enhanced network connectivity.  See ADD100 (competing domestic carriers “commonly” make arrangements for codesharing and loyalty reciprocity to benefits consumers); ADD25 (the West Coast International Alliance includes codesharing and reciprocal benefits); see also ADD27 (no other domestic airline joint venture has received antitrust scrutiny).

In no sense does the NEA fit into the category of agreements that are so facially anticompetitive that they merit a presumption of illegality.  Rather, the NEA reflects efforts to construct integrated national networks—responding in part to consumer choice expansion pressures from low-cost carrier growth, and in part to competitive pressures from other major carriers in the region.  See ADD21 (“It is against this backdrop of industry consolidation, in this competitive landscape . . . that the agreement at issue here arose.”).  The NEA established intricate revenue-sharing calculations, reciprocal loyalty programs, coordinated scheduling committees, and joint corporate customer arrangements—all premised on maximizing efficiency and reducing operational costs.  See 1-JA342, 1-JA348, 2-JA1224-25.

These provisions aimed at forging a unified domestic connector system warrant more than a quick look before abandoning them as hopeless.  Indeed, the Opinion accepted that the NEA generated capacity increases at slot-constrained airports in the Northeast region, while expressing concern “that capacity growth within the NEA comes at the expense of resources and output by the defendants elsewhere, as well as evidence the defendants each would have pursued at least some of this growth with or without the partnership.”  ADD95-ADD96.  Neither theoretically nor actually did the NEA reflect a naked restraint on output or pricing.  The important point is not to settle whether there was a net capacity increase or a reallocation that increased consumer welfare.  The important point is that, at minimum, such contractual complexities command a balanced rule of reason review rather than a truncated analysis through thinly substantiated assumptions.

By dispensing with the NEA with an abbreviated analysis, the Opinion departed from binding case-law.  See Alston, 141 S. Ct. at 2155 (joint ventures “are subject to the rule of reason, which (again) we have described as ‘a fact-specific assessment of market power and market structure’ aimed at assessing the challenged restraint’s ‘actual effect on competition’”) (citing Am. Express Co., 138 S. Ct. at 2284); Augusta News, 269 F.3d at 48 (“[I]t is commonly understood today that per se condemnation is limited to ‘naked’ market division agreements, that is, to those that are not part of a larger pro-competitive joint venture.”).

CONCLUSION

Because the district court equated competition to the number of competitors, effectively treated the NEA erroneously as a horizontal merger, and applied an improper, truncated analysis far short of a full rule of reason analysis, this Court should reverse the judgment of the district court and vacate the permanent injunction.

[1] Under Rule 29(a)(4)(E) of the Federal Rules of Appellate Procedure, amici certify that (i) no party’s counsel authored the brief in-whole or in-part; (ii) no party or a party’s counsel contributed money that was intended to fund preparing or submitting the brief; and (iii) no person, other than amici or its counsel, contributed money that was intended to fund preparing or submitting the brief.

[2] All parties have consented to the filing of this brief.

[3] “ADD” refers to the Addendum attached to the Appellant’s Brief.  “JA” refers to the Joint Appendix filed with the Appellant’s Brief.

Continue reading
Antitrust & Consumer Protection