Showing Latest Publications

In Apple v Pepper, SCOTUS leaves home without its Amex

TOTM It might surprise some readers to learn that we think the Court’s decision today in Apple v. Pepper reaches — superficially — the correct result. But, we hasten to add, the Court’s reasoning (and, for that matter, the dissent’s) is completely wrongheaded.

It might surprise some readers to learn that we think the Court’s decision today in Apple v. Pepper reaches — superficially — the correct result. But, we hasten to add, the Court’s reasoning (and, for that matter, the dissent’s) is completely wrongheaded. It would be an understatement to say that the Court reached the right result for the wrong reason; in fact, the Court’s analysis wasn’t even in the same universe as the correct reasoning.

Read the full piece here.

Continue reading
Antitrust & Consumer Protection

Is Amazon Guilty of Predatory Pricing?

TOTM Predatory pricing is a rather rare anticompetitive practice because the “predator” runs the risk of bankrupting itself in the process of trying to drive rivals out of business with below-cost pricing.

In 2014, Benedict Evans, a venture capitalist at Andreessen Horowitz, wrote “Why Amazon Has No Profits (And Why It Works),” a blog post in which he tried to explain Amazon’s business model. He began with a chart of Amazon’s revenue and net income that has now become (in)famous…

Read the full piece here.

 

Continue reading
Antitrust & Consumer Protection

The ICANN Board’s Important Test of Independence: .Amazon

TOTM One of the main concerns I had during the IANA transition was the extent to which the newly independent organization would be able to behave impartially, implementing . . .

One of the main concerns I had during the IANA transition was the extent to which the newly independent organization would be able to behave impartially, implementing its own policies and bylaws in an objective and non-discriminatory manner, and not be unduly influenced by specific  “stakeholders”. Chief among my concerns at the time was the extent to which an independent ICANN would be able to resist the influence of governments: when a powerful government leaned on ICANN’s board, would it be able to adhere to its own policies and follow the process the larger multistakeholder community put in place?

Read the full piece here.

Continue reading
Antitrust & Consumer Protection

Deadweight loss from no monopoly

TOTM The once-mighty Blockbuster video chain is now down to a single store, in Bend, Oregon. It appears to be the only video rental store in Bend, aside from those offering “adult” features. Does that make Blockbuster a monopoly?

The once-mighty Blockbuster video chain is now down to a single store, in Bend, Oregon. It appears to be the only video rental store in Bend, aside from those offering “adult” features. Does that make Blockbuster a monopoly?

Read the full piece here.

Continue reading
Antitrust & Consumer Protection

BRIEF OF RICHARD A. EPSTEIN & GEOFFREY A. MANNE, IN SUPPORT OF Defendant in Pulse Network, LLC v. Visa Incorporated

Amicus Brief To establish antitrust standing, Pulse must show not only “injury causally linked to an illegal presence in the market” but also antitrust injury “attributable to an anti-competitive aspect of the practice under scrutiny.”

Summary

To establish antitrust standing, Pulse must show not only “injury causally linked to an illegal presence in the market” but also antitrust injury “attributable to an anti-competitive aspect of the practice under scrutiny.” Atl. Richfield Co. v. USA Petroleum Co., 495 U.S. 328, 334 (1990) (quoting Brunswick Corp. v. Pueblo Bowl-O-Mat, Inc., 429 U.S. 477, 488-89 (1977)). Put differently, Pulse must prove the existence of an injury “of the type the antitrust laws were intended to prevent and that flows from that which makes defendants’ acts unlawful.” Id. (quoting Brunswick Corp., 429 U.S. at 489). As the district court rightly decided, Pulse has failed to meet its burden.

Antitrust law does not punish firms for succeeding even if they become dominant. Congress enacted the Sherman Act for “the protection of competition, not competitors.” Id. at 338 (quoting Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S. 294, 320 (1962)). Yet Pulse’s injury flows from increased competition due to Visa’s innovation in the debit- network industry. Pulse freely admits that it lacks the “scale and market relevance” needed to compete with Visa’s challenged business strategies. (Appellant’s Br. 34) That Pulse’s PIN product has (so far, anyway) failed to gain traction in the marketplace, however, is not proof of antitrust injury. On the contrary, mere injury to a competitor, rather than to competition, is not an injury “of the type the antitrust laws were intended to prevent.” Phototron Corp. v. Eastman Kodak Co., 842 F.2d 95, 99 (5th Cir. 1988) (quoting Brunswick Corp., 429 U.S. at 489).

What’s more, Pulse has sued Visa for conduct that Pulse admits lowered merchants’ per-transaction fees, contending that those lower fees caused Pulse to obtain fewer transactions and generate less revenue. Pulse complains that it cannot “undercut” Visa’s new pricing structure. (Appellant’s Br. 40) But non-predatory price competition is no basis for antitrust injury. “When a firm … lowers prices but maintains them above predatory levels, the business lost by rivals cannot be viewed as an ‘anticompetitive’ consequence of the claimed violation.” Atl. Richfield, 495 U.S. at 337. So even if it harms Pulse, Visa’s charging low, but not below-cost, per-transaction fees to win market share is not harm to competition. Instead, both Visa’s conduct and its effects are “fully consistent with competition on the merits.” Taylor Publ’g Co. v. Jostens, Inc., 216 F.3d 465, 477 (5th Cir. 2000).

True, when assessing standing, this Court will assume that an antitrust violation exists. Doctor’s Hosp. of Jefferson, Inc. v. Se. Med. All., Inc., 123 F.3d 301, 306 (5th Cir. 1997). But that is not enough. “[P]roof of a[n antitrust] violation and of antitrust injury are distinct matters that must be shown independently.” Atl. Richfield, 495 U.S. at 344 (quoting Phillip E. Areeda & Herbert Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law ¶ 334.2c, at 330 (1989 Supp.)). Unable to show how Visa’s conduct harmed competition in any way, Pulse seeks to wag the dog of antitrust injury with the tail of an assumed violation. But a competitor has standing only if it proves that its “loss stems from a competition- reducing aspect or effect of the defendant’s behavior.” Atl. Richfield, 495 U.S. at 344. Pulse has proven nothing of the sort.

Antitrust is about unleashing the forces of competition, not throttling them. Accepting Pulse’s watered-down approach to antitrust injury, however, would have just the opposite effect. It would invite struggling firms to use antitrust law as a sword rather than a shield. It would deter innovation in highly competitive markets. And it would permit competitors to seek treble damages for pro-competitive harms that antitrust law does not reach. Rather than ensure vigorous competition, reversing the judgment below would harm competition and consumers alike.

Click here to read the full brief.

Continue reading
Antitrust & Consumer Protection

Is European Competition Law Protectionist? Unpacking the Commission’s Unflattering Track Record

TOTM In a new ICLE Issue Brief, we question whether there is any merit to these claims of protectionism. We show that, since the entry into force of Regulation 1/2003, US firms have borne the lion’s share of monetary penalties imposed by the Commission for breaches of competition law.

Last month, the European Commission slapped another fine upon Google for infringing European competition rules (€1.49 billion this time). This brings Google’s contribution to the EU budget to a dizzying total of €8.25 billion (to put this into perspective, the total EU budget for 2019 is €165.8 billion). Given this massive number, and the geographic location of Google’s headquarters, it is perhaps not surprising that some high-profile commentators, including former President Obama and President Trump, have raised concerns about potential protectionism on the Commission’s part.

Read the full piece here.

Continue reading
Antitrust & Consumer Protection

ICLE Affiliate Thibault Schrepel Discusses Blockchain, Free Markets, and Antitrust Laws on Competition Lore Podcast

Presentations & Interviews A tripartite conversation between Glen Weyl, Caron Beaton-Wells, and ICLE affiliate Thibault Schrepel about blockchain, but also free markets, state power and the (absence of) . . .

A tripartite conversation between Glen Weyl, Caron Beaton-Wells, and ICLE affiliate Thibault Schrepel about blockchain, but also free markets, state power and the (absence of) need for antitrust laws. Description taken from the Competition Lore podcast below. The full episode is embedded below.

Continue reading
Antitrust & Consumer Protection

Amazon is not essential

TOTM The following is adapted from a recent ICLE Issue Brief on the flawed essential facilities arguments undergirding the EU competition investigations into Amazon’s marketplace that Kristian Stout wrote with Geoffrey Manne.

Amazon has largely avoided the crosshairs of antitrust enforcers to date. The reasons seem obvious: in the US it handles a mere 5% of all retail sales (with lower shares worldwide), and it consistently provides access to a wide array of affordable goods. Yet, even with Amazon’s obvious lack of dominance in the general retail market, the EU and some of its member states are opening investigations.

Read the full piece here.

Continue reading
Antitrust & Consumer Protection

This Too Shall Pass: Unassailable Monopolies That Were, in Hindsight, Eminently Assailable

TOTM Elizabeth Warren wants to break up the tech giants — Facebook, Google, Amazon, and Apple — claiming they have too much power and represent a danger to our democracy. As part of our response to her proposal, we shared a couple of headlines from 2007 claiming that MySpace had an unassailable monopoly in the social media market.

Elizabeth Warren wants to break up the tech giants — Facebook, Google, Amazon, and Apple — claiming they have too much power and represent a danger to our democracy. As part of our response to her proposal, we shared a couple of headlines from 2007 claiming that MySpace had an unassailable monopoly in the social media market.

Read the full piece here.

Continue reading
Antitrust & Consumer Protection