Showing 9 of 27 Publications

Lazar Radic on the UK’s Digital Markets Bill

Presentations & Interviews ICLE Senior Scholar Lazar Radic joined Institute of Economic Affairs (IEA) Director of Public Policy and Communications Matthew Lesh on the IEA Podcast to discuss . . .

ICLE Senior Scholar Lazar Radic joined Institute of Economic Affairs (IEA) Director of Public Policy and Communications Matthew Lesh on the IEA Podcast to discuss the new joint ICLE-IEA paper “Digital Overload: How the Digital Markets, Competition and Consumers Bill’s Sweeping New Powers Threaten Britain’s Economy.” Video of the full podcast is embedded below.

Continue reading
Antitrust & Consumer Protection

The Digital Competition and Consumers Bill Threatens to Wrap UK Tech in Red Tape

Popular Media The UK has long prided itself as an attractive destination for investors and a hub for innovation. This is no small part due to the . . .

The UK has long prided itself as an attractive destination for investors and a hub for innovation. This is no small part due to the country’s sensible and proportionate, evidence-based approach to regulation, which focuses on correcting market failures. But a new bill currently in Parliament risks undermining Britain’s status as a regulatory role model, as well as Rishi Sunak’s ambition to turn the UK into a “science and technology superpower.” The Digital Competition and Consumers Bill (DMCC) takes its inspiration from the EU’s Digital Markets Act. The DMCC would give the Competition and Market Authority’s (CMA) expansive new powers to prohibit or compel conduct in digital markets, with potentially far-reaching implications for consumers, investment, innovation, and the country’s overall competitiveness.

Read the full piece here.

Continue reading
Antitrust & Consumer Protection

The FTC’s Gambit Against Amazon: Navigating a Multiverse of Blowback and Consumer Harm

TOTM The Federal Trade Commission (FTC) is reportedly poised some time within the next month to file a major antitrust lawsuit against Amazon—the biggest yet against . . .

The Federal Trade Commission (FTC) is reportedly poised some time within the next month to file a major antitrust lawsuit against Amazon—the biggest yet against the company and the latest in a long string of cases targeting U.S. tech firms (see, for example, here and here). While specific details of the suit remain largely unknown and subject to changes up to the 11th hour, according to Politico, the FTC’s multi-pronged case is likely to focus on three aspects… Read the full piece here.
Continue reading
Antitrust & Consumer Protection

ICLE Amicus in En Banc Rehearing Before the 9th Circuit in Epic Games v Apple

Amicus Brief INTEREST OF THE AMICUS CURIAE The International Center for Law & Economics (“ICLE”) is a nonprofit, non-partisan global research and policy center aimed at building . . .

INTEREST OF THE AMICUS CURIAE

The International Center for Law & Economics (“ICLE”) is a nonprofit, non-partisan global research and policy center aimed at building the intellectual foundations for sensible, economically grounded policy.  ICLE promotes the use of law and economics methodologies to inform policy debates and has longstanding expertise evaluating antitrust law and policy.

ICLE has an interest in ensuring that antitrust law promotes the public interest by remaining grounded in sensible rules informed by sound economic analysis.  That includes ensuring consistency between antitrust law and other laws that proscribe unfair methods of competition, such as California’s Unfair Competition Law.[1]

INTRODUCTION

The panel’s holdings that (1) Apple’s conduct with respect to its close control over the App Store and restrictions on in-app payments (“IAP”) do not give rise to an antitrust violation, but that (2) its anti-steering provisions nevertheless violate California’s Unfair Competition Law (“UCL”), are incongruent.  The anti-steering provisions violate the UCL only if they constitute an “incipient violation of an antitrust law, or . . . [cause harm] comparable to or the same as a violation of the law.”  Cel-Tech Commc’ns, Inc. v. L.A. Cellular Tel. Co., 20 Cal. 4th 163, 186-87 (1999).  But provisions limiting app developers’ ability to steer consumers to alternative payment options exist merely to further the goals of the lawful IAP restrictions, and thus the anti-steering provisions cannot constitute incipient antitrust violations or cause harm comparable to such violations.

Having affirmed the District Court’s finding that Apple’s IAP policies are procompetitive, the panel should have ruled that Apple’s anti-steering provisions—which constitute a less restrictive means of pursuing the same procompetitive objective—are not unfair under the UCL.  The panel’s decision, if it stands, risks chilling procompetitive conduct by deterring investment in efficiency-enhancing business practices, such as Apple’s “walled-garden” iOS.  See Verizon Commc’ns, Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 540 U.S. 398, 414 (2004) (“[F]alse condemnations ‘are especially costly, because they chill the very conduct the antitrust laws are designed to protect.’”) (quoting Matsushita Elec. Indus. Co. v. Zenith Radio Corp., 475 U.S. 574, 594 (1986)).  More egregiously, it risks creating a fundamental contradiction by enjoining conduct under the UCL that is benign—and even beneficial—under antitrust law.

ARGUMENT

I.              Antitrust Laws and Laws on Unfair Methods of Competition Share the Same Goal: Protecting Competition, not Competitors

Antitrust and other laws aimed at proscribing unfair methods of competition (“UMC”) share the same overarching rationale, and thus “we can classify unfair competition and antitrust as blood brothers or, at least, as brothers-in-law.”  Rudolf Callmann, Unfair Competition and Antitrust: Coexistence Within Complementary Goals, 13 Antitrust Bull. 1335, 1335 (1968).  Both types of laws were enacted to protect consumers by protecting “competition, not competitors.” Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S. 294, 320 (1962) (emphasis in original); accord Cel-Tech, 20 Cal. 4th at 186-87 (citing this language and defining “unfair” in the UCL to include incipient antitrust violations and other conduct that “significantly threatens or harms competition”) (emphasis added).

Thus, while harm to a competitor may provide an evidentiary basis for demonstrating harm to competition under both antitrust and UMC laws, it is not sufficient for a viable claim under either.  Indeed, just as conduct that constitutes vigorous competition in one context can cause anticompetitive harm in another, so too may conduct that harms a competitor promote competition overall.  Spectrum Sports, Inc. v. McQuillan, 506 U.S. 447, 458-59 (1993) (“The law directs itself not against conduct which is competitive, even severely so, but against conduct which unfairly tends to destroy competition itself . . . . It is sometimes difficult to distinguish robust competition from conduct with long-term anticompetitive effects . . . .”); New York v. Microsoft Corp., 224 F. Supp. 2d 76 (D.D.C. 2002) (“conduct that is in some respect adverse to competitors is almost implicit in the concept of competition”).  In order to avoid condemning beneficial conduct, only a few forms of conduct are per se antitrust violations, and the vast majority are assessed based on their economic effects.

UMC law is nominally more focused on the nature of the conduct at issue—whether it is “unfair.”  As in antitrust, a few forms of conduct are facially problematic under UMC law.  Most notably, conduct that violates some other law or policy may also violate UMC law.[2]  But where the basis for an unfairness claim under UMC law is inchoate harm to competition, decades of scholarship and judicial decisions have made clear that the conduct should be assessed using the same principles and effects-based logic of antitrust.  “[A] rigid separation of the antitrust laws and the law of unfair competition is neither legally realistic nor economically desirable.”  Callmann, supra, at 1345.

The same is true under the UCL: “[T]he determination of whether a particular business practice is unfair necessarily involves an examination of its impact on its alleged victim, balanced against the reasons, justifications and motives of the alleged wrongdoer.  In brief, the court must weigh the utility of the defendant’s conduct against the gravity of the harm to the alleged victim.”  Motors, Inc. v. Times Mirror Co., 102 Cal. App. 3d 735, 740 (Cal. Ct. App. 1980).

The logic is simple.  Because consumers benefit from vigorous competition, antitrust law does not punish companies for competing on the merits, even if rivals are harmed or eliminated as a result.  See Spectrum Sports, 506 U.S. at 458; Copperweld Corp. v. Indep. Tube Corp., 467 U.S. 752, 758, 767 (1984); NYNEX v. Discon, 525 U.S. 128, 135-36, 139 (1998).  Using UMC laws to ban conduct merely because it harms competitors would risk undermining the very rationale of competition and, by extension, the UMC laws that seek to protect it.  See Cel-Tech, 20 Cal. 4th at 185 (an improper definition of unfair “may even lead to the enjoining of procompetitive conduct and thereby undermine consumer protection, the primary purpose of the antitrust laws”) (emphasis in original).  Under UMC law as under antitrust law, “[c]ourts must be careful not to . . . prevent rigorous, but fair, competitive strategies that all companies are free to meet or counter with their own strategies.  Companies that cannot compete with others that are more capable or efficient may lawfully fail.”  Id.

A.            The Unified Interpretation of UMC and Anticompetitive Conduct under the Antitrust Laws Is Well Established

As the California Supreme Court has held, in order to establish the meaning of “unfair” under the UCL, “we may turn for guidance to the jurisprudence arising under the ‘parallel’ Section 5 of the Federal Trade Commission Act.  ‘In view of the similarity of language and obvious identity of purpose of the two statutes, decisions of the federal court on the subject are more than ordinarily persuasive.’”  Cel-Tech, 20 Cal. 4th at 185 (citations omitted).

“As with the Sherman Act, conduct challenged under Section 5 ‘must have an “anticompetitive effect.’”  That is, it must harm the competitive process and thereby harm consumers.  In contrast, harm to one or more competitors will not suffice.’”  Statement of FTC Commissioner Joshua D. Wright on the Proposed Policy Statement Regarding Unfair Methods of Competition under Section 5 of the Federal Trade Commission Act, at 7 (June 19, 2013) (quoting United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34, 58 (D.C. Cir. 2001) (en banc)).

Indeed, in the more than 100 years of history interpreting the FTC Act, “[a]n understanding emerged that the FTC’s UMC authority reached somewhat beyond the Sherman Act, but was still tethered to the central antitrust concepts of the consumer welfare standard and the ‘rule of reason,’ both of which offer courts a means to evaluate the legality of market behavior in terms of its likely harms and benefits.”  Geoffrey A. Manne & Daniel Gilman, FTC UMC Authority: Uncertain Scope, Int’l Ctr. for L. & Econ. (Jan. 19, 2023), https://laweconcenter.org/resources/ftc-umc-authority-uncertain-scope/.

The legislative history of the FTC Act makes clear its alignment with the principle of “harm to competition, not competitors” undergirding antitrust law: “The unfairness must be tinctured with unfairness to the public; not merely with unfairness to the rival or competitor . . . .  We are not simply trying to protect one man against another; we are trying to protect the people of the United States, and of course, there must be in the imposture or in the vicious practice or method something that has a tendency to affect the people of the country or be injurious to their welfare.”  51 Cong. Rec. 11,105 (1914) (Remarks of Senator Cummins).

Scholars have developed a robust body of work confirming that the FTC Act was meant to supplement the Sherman Act.  See, e.g., Gregory J. Werden, Unfair Methods of Competition under Section 5 of the Federal Trade Commission Act: What Is the Intelligible Principle?, Mercatus Center Working Paper 4, 19-22 (2023).  And even former FTC Chairman William Kovacic has written that the FTC “should not . . . rely on the assertion . . . that the Commission could use its UMC authority to reach practices outside both the letter and spirit of the antitrust laws.”  William E. Kovacic & Marc Winerman, Competition Policy and the Application of Section 5 of the Federal Trade Commission Act, 76 Antitrust L.J. 929, 945 (2010).

While these statements relate to federal statutes, the more general point on the shared rationale between antitrust and unfair competition laws extends beyond the specific relationship between the Sherman and Clayton Acts on the one hand, and the FTC Act on the other.  In fact, the California Court of Appeals has explicitly endorsed this view, finding that, where the same conduct is “alleged to be both an antitrust violation and an ‘unfair’ business act or practice for the same reason—because it unreasonably restrains competition and harms consumers—the determination that the conduct is not an unreasonable restraint of trade necessarily implies that the conduct is not ‘unfair’ toward consumers.”  Chavez v. Whirlpool Corp., 93 Cal. App. 4th 363, 375 (Cal. Ct. App. 2001).

True, in Cel-Tech an “unfair” claim was allowed to proceed despite the plaintiff failing to make out an antitrust violation.  Cel-Tech, 20 Cal. 4th 163.  But Cel-Tech is the rare case where anticompetitive conduct—below cost sales—may be actionable under the UCL but not under antitrust law because of the idiosyncratic structure of the industry and the regulatory context.  See id. at 189 (“This case has an unusual circumstance that might bring it within the unfair competition law’s coverage. . . . ‘[F]air and honest competition’ in equipment sales might not be possible when a legally privileged company sells equipment below cost as a strategy to increase profits on service sales that are prohibited to its equipment competitors.”).  Ultimately, however, the underlying logic of the UCL and antitrust claims in Cel-Tech was rooted in the same unified goal: protecting competition.

The case at hand, however, is fundamentally different.  Here, Epic is essentially asking that Apple be forced to aid its competitors, a position that is contrary to the ethos of both antitrust law and the UCL.

B.            The Connection Between Unfair Competition and Anticompetitive Conduct Is Recognized by California Courts

The UCL contains three distinct bases for establishing a violation, two of which are relevant here: “unfair competition shall mean and include any unlawful, unfair or fraudulent business act or practice . . . .”  Cal. Bus. & Prof. Code § 17200 (emphasis added).[3]  But the panel erred when it declared that requiring a violation of antitrust law would collapse the unlawful and unfair prongs of this disjunctive standard.  While there is inevitably overlap between the assessment of antitrust law under the two prongs (because “unfairness” inherently imports antitrust concepts and standards), the “unlawful” prong is not rendered a nullity by the role of antitrust standards in assessing the unfairness prong because that prong relates to laws other than antitrust.  Actual violations of antitrust law may also constitute violations of the UCL.  See, e.g., In re Keurig Green Mountain Single-Serve Coffee Antitrust Litig., 383 F. Supp. 3d 187, 267 (S.D.N.Y. 2019) (“Because I have concluded that the IPPs have adequately pleaded that Keurig’s conduct was an unfair restraint of trade, I also conclude that they have adequately pleaded that it was unfair under the California Unfair Competition Law.”).

Thus, the court in Cel-Tech first addressed potential non-antitrust sources of harm and then considered the role of antitrust law only in its exegesis of the “unfair” prong of the UCL.  That is why the decision considered whether (1) any provision of the California Unfair Practices Act offers a basis for liability or provides a “safe harbor” from liability, or (2) stated policies of the California Public Utilities Commission could be undermined by the conduct in question.  Cel-Tech, 20 Cal. 4th at 182-91.

The California Supreme Court then separately considered whether antitrust law might serve as a basis for liability, and did so under the “unfair” prong of the UCL.  There, it established that “the word ‘unfair’ in [the UCL] . . . means conduct that threatens an incipient violation of an antitrust law, or violates the policy or spirit of one of those laws because its effects are comparable to or the same as a violation of the law, or otherwise significantly threatens or harms competition.”  Cel-Tech, 20 Cal. 4th at 187.  It is impossible to read this as holding that a violation of the “unfair” prong of the UCL can arise from conduct other than conduct that would violate the antitrust laws.

Most relevant here, the court strongly cautioned against imposing liability for conduct that would not otherwise be an antitrust violation because “[c]ourts must not prohibit ‘vigorous competition’ nor ‘render illegal any decision by a firm to cut prices in order to increase market share.”  Id. at 189 (quoting Cargill, Inc. v. Monfort of Colo., Inc., 479 U.S. 104, 116 (1986)).  Doing so would lead to a harmful and improper incongruity between the UCL and the antitrust laws.

By the same token, in Chavez a California Court of Appeals held:

If the same conduct is alleged to be both an antitrust violation and an “unfair” business act or practice for the same reason—because it unreasonably restrains competition and harms consumer—the determination that the conduct is not an unreasonable restraint of trade necessarily implies that the conduct is not “unfair” toward consumers. To permit a separate inquiry into essentially the same question under the unfair competition law would only invite conflict and uncertainty and could lead to the enjoining of procompetitive conduct.

113 Cal. Rptr. 2d at 184.  The panel asserts that this admonition is limited only to “categorical antitrust rule[s].”  Epic Games, Inc. v. Apple, Inc., 67 F.4th 946, 1001 (9th Cir. 2023).  But California’s Second District Court of Appeals clarified that:

[w]e do not hold that in all circumstances an “unfair” business act or practice must violate an antitrust law to be actionable under the unfair competition law.  Instead we hold that conduct alleged to be “unfair” because it unreasonably restrains competition and harms consumers, such as the resale price maintenance agreement alleged here, is not “unfair” if the conduct is deemed reasonable and condoned under the antitrust laws.

Chavez, 113 Cal. Rptr. 2d at 184.

II.           Apple’s Anti-Steering Provisions Cannot Be Unfair as a Matter of Law

The litigation at hand is a case-study on why conduct that is procompetitive should not be enjoined under the UCL.

Apple’s Guidelines included two types of anti-steering provisions that were aimed at preventing third-party apps from directing customers to purchasing mechanisms other than Apple’s IAP: (1) a prohibition on links or buttons within third-party apps; and (2) a prohibition on targeted communications outside of the apps.

Apple has deleted (2) as part of the Cameron v. Apple Inc. settlement, meaning that developers are now free to communicate outside of the apps about external purchasing options (or anything else).  See Order: Granting Mot. for Final Approval of Class Action Settlement; Granting in Part and Denying in Part Mot. for Attorney’s Fees, Costs, and Service Award; and Judgment at 12, No. 19-cv-03074 (N.D. Cal. June 10, 2022).  What remains is the prohibition on links and buttons within apps.  The question is therefore whether such a prohibition is unfair within the meaning of the UCL.

A.            Unfairness under the UCL

The panel claims that the California Supreme Court has identified two tests to assess liability under the UCL’s “unfair” prong: “First, to support ‘any finding of unfairness to competitors,’ a court uses the ‘tethering’ test . . . .  Second, to support a finding of unfairness to consumers, a court uses the balancing test . . . .”  Epic Games, 67 F.4th at 1000 (citations omitted).

But it is incorrect that the California Supreme Court has identified these two tests; rather, the California Supreme Court identified only the tethering test and left unsettled whether there should be a separate test for claims brought by consumers.  Cel-Tech, 20 Cal. 4th at 187 n.12 (“This case involves an action by a competitor alleging anticompetitive practices. Our discussion and this test are limited to that context.  Nothing we say relates to actions by consumers . . . .”).

Despite the confusion generated by the Cel-Tech court’s failure to provide a test for consumer-initiated claims under the UCL, ultimately it should not matter whether the case is resolved under the tethering test or the balancing test.  As discussed above, the aim of both the antitrust laws and UMC laws is to promote consumer welfare by protecting competition—regardless of whether the underlying conduct is in the first instance “unfair” to consumers or competitors.  See Cel-Tech, 20 Cal. 4th at 186 (noting the aim of the test it enumerates to identify unfairness to competitors is “to promote consumer protection”); see also id. at 206 (Kennard, J. concurring and dissenting) (“The purpose of competition is to drive prices down.  Although the unfair competition law protects competitors, even under the majority’s definition it does not protect competitors at the expense of competition.”).

Thus, while the evidentiary basis for claims brought by different parties may be distinct, the ultimate test of harm is not: finding injury to consumers.  But even on this point, the supposed differences between the two tests are largely formalistic.  The so-called “balancing test,” which the panel asserts should apply to unfairness claims brought by consumers, is effectively the same as the burden-shifting, rule-of-reason assessment under antitrust law—which is similarly reflected in the “tethering test” applied to claims brought by competitors.

The anti-steering provisions therefore cannot be considered substantially injurious to consumers because it has already been established that consumers on the whole benefit from Apple requiring the use of its IAP.

B.            UMC under Claims Brought by Competitors

Unfairness to competitors is explicitly resolved through the “tethering test,” which asks whether the defendant’s conduct “threatens an incipient violation of an antitrust law, or violates the policy or spirit of one of those laws because its effects are comparable to or the same as a violation of the law, or otherwise significantly threatens or harms competition.”  Cel-Tech, 20 Cal. 4th at 186-87.

Any of these three bases for liability implicates harm to consumers, which antitrust law generally defines in terms of reduced output or increased prices for consumers.  The first basis for finding unfairness—an incipient violation of an antitrust law—concerns conduct that has not yet harmed consumers but is almost certain to do so in the future.

The second basis—the “policy or spirit” of antitrust law provision—is violated when conduct results in “effects [that] are comparable to or the same as a violation of” antitrust law.  Id. at 187.  Under this provision, whether anyone labels the challenged conduct an antitrust violation is irrelevant; instead, what matters is whether the conduct results in the same anticompetitive effects as an antitrust violation, and courts should pursue this inquiry as they would any other inquiry into the competitive effects of challenged conduct.

The third basis—conduct that “otherwise significantly threatens or harms competition”—is a catch-all meant to capture conduct that is permitted under the antitrust laws but nevertheless results in harm to competition.  The most obvious such circumstance is the very one assessed in Cel-Tech where the defendant was given a privileged legal status in the market at issue, and the threat was to a specifically defined form of competition under other laws or regulatory policies.

Accordingly, to resolve the question of whether Apple’s anti-steering provision is unfair, an inquiry must be made into whether the conduct has anticompetitive effects—i.e., whether it harms consumers by reducing output without concomitant procompetitive benefits—or whether it would, if left unchecked, likely develop into such an infringement.

C.            The Answer to the “Unfairness” Question Is Anticipated by the Findings under Antitrust Law

In rejecting Epic’s claims under federal antitrust law, the district court and the panel have effectively foreclosed an unfairness claim under the UCL.

The panel found that Apple’s walled-garden iOS, which prohibits third-party IAPs and app stores, did not violate federal antitrust laws because of its pro-competitive benefits: i.e., increased user privacy and security that could not be achieved through less restrictive means and that ultimately increased inter-brand competition between Apple’s iOS and its closest competitor, Android.  In parallel, however, the panel concluded that Apple’s anti-steering provisions, which prohibit apps from informing users about payment possibilities other than IAP, were unfair under the UCL.

In other words, Apple remains free to prohibit third-party IAPs based on the findings of procompetitive benefits, yet, at the same time, Apple is enjoined from prohibiting links or buttons to third-party payment mechanisms—a less-restrictive means of furthering the same objective.  The two holdings cannot be reconciled.

The prohibition of links and buttons within the app is an enforcement mechanism for the prohibition of third-party IAPs.  If Apple is allowed to require its own IAP on security and privacy grounds, then surely prohibiting apps from encouraging users to bypass Apple’s IAP—by directing consumers to alternative payment methods which may be less secure or private—supports those same procompetitive benefits that the courts recognized.  Other courts have correctly concluded that the same conduct cannot be both procompetitive and unfair.  See Hicks v. PGA Tour, Inc., 897 F.3d 1109, 1124 (9th Cir. 2018); City of San Jose v. Off. of the Comm’r of Baseball, 776 F.3d 686, 691-92 (9th Cir. 2015).

While the anti-steering provision and the requirement that Apple’s IAP be used are not technically identical, they are both instrumental to achieving the same objective.  Thus, even if the Ninth Circuit’s conclusions under federal antitrust law on the IAP were not sufficient to automatically preclude a UMC claim related to the anti-steering provisions, an independent analysis under the UCL should—if done properly—reach the same conclusion: Apple’s anti-steering provisions, like its IAP exclusivity requirement, are procompetitive, do not harm competition, and therefore cannot be considered unfair.

Furthermore, despite the panel’s assertion that its finding of legality under the Sherman Act did not mean that Apple’s conduct was “categorically” permitted under Cel-Tech, Epic Games, 2023 U.S. App. LEXIS 9775, at *96-97, it is settled case-law that, in the absence of any purpose to create or maintain a monopoly, Apple has a “categorical” right to choose with whom it does business.  See, e.g., Trinko, 540 U.S. at 408; Pac. Bell Tel. Co. v. Linkline Commc’ns, Inc., 555 U.S. 438, 448 (2009); Chavez, 113 Cal. Rptr. 2d at 182-83.  “The antitrust laws [do] not impose a duty on [firms] . . . to assist [competitors] . . . to ‘survive or expand.’”  Foremost Pro Color, Inc. v. Eastman Kodak Co., 703 F.2d 534, 545 (9th Cir. 1983) (citations omitted).  Apple is under no obligation to facilitate third-party payment options—much less if this jeopardizes the integrity of its iOS.

CONCLUSION

For the foregoing reasons, this Court should grant Apple’s rehearing request to clarify that Apple’s conduct violated neither the antitrust laws nor the UCL.

[1] ICLE represents that no party’s counsel authored this brief in whole or in part, no party or party’s counsel contributed money that was intended to fund preparing or submitting the brief, and no person—other than ICLE and its counsel—contributed money that was intended to fund preparing or submitting the brief.  ICLE files this brief pursuant with consent of all parties.

[2] This is reflected in the UCL’s language prohibiting “unlawful” conduct.  See Cel-Tech, 20 Cal. 4th at 180 (“By proscribing ‘any unlawful’ business practice, ‘[the UCL] “borrows” violations of other laws and treats them as unlawful practices’ that the unfair competition law makes independently actionable.”) (citations omitted).

[3] It is worth noting that the dissenting opinion in Cel-Tech takes issue with the majority’s decision that the “unfair” prong of the UCL means anything other than “deceptive.”  Under this reading of the UCL, of course, there would be no basis for the district court or the panel’s finding that Apple’s conduct violated the UCL.  See Cel-Tech, 20 Cal. 4th at 192 (Kennard J. dissenting) (“The purpose of the legal prohibitions against unfair business acts and practices, by contrast, is to prevent deceptive conduct that injures a particular competitor.”).

Continue reading
Antitrust & Consumer Protection

Untangling the 9th Circuit’s Ruling in Epic Games v Apple

TOTM The 9th U.S. Circuit Court of Appeals ruled late last month on Epic Games’ appeal of the decision rendered in 2021 by the U.S. District Court for . . .

The 9th U.S. Circuit Court of Appeals ruled late last month on Epic Games’ appeal of the decision rendered in 2021 by the U.S. District Court for the Northern District of California in Epic Games v Apple, affirming in part and reversing in part the district court’s judgment.

Read the full piece here.

Continue reading
Antitrust & Consumer Protection

Digital-Market Regulation: One Size Does Not Fit All

TOTM Regulators around the globe are scrambling for a silver bullet to “tame” tech companies. Whether it’s the United States, the United Kingdom, Australia, South Africa, or Canada, the animating rationale behind such . . .

Regulators around the globe are scrambling for a silver bullet to “tame” tech companies. Whether it’s the United States, the United KingdomAustraliaSouth Africa, or Canada, the animating rationale behind such efforts is that firms like Google, Apple, Meta, and Amazon (GAMA) engage in undesirable market conduct that falls beyond the narrow purview of antitrust law (here and here).

Read the full piece here.

Continue reading
Antitrust & Consumer Protection

Exploring the Outer Boundaries of Antitrust: Antitrust as Industrial Policy?

Presentations & Interviews Video from the International Center for Law & Economics’ (ICLE) March 24, 2023 event “Exploring the Outer Boundaries of Antitrust: Democracy, Sustainability, & Industrial Policy” . . .

Video from the International Center for Law & Economics’ (ICLE) March 24, 2023 event “Exploring the Outer Boundaries of Antitrust: Democracy, Sustainability, & Industrial Policy” in Madrid, Spain. In a panel moderated by ICLE Senior Scholar Lazar Radic, panelists Frederic Jenny, chairman of the OECD Competition Committee; Wendy Ng, associate professor of law at Melbourne Law School; Don Rosenberg, resident fellow at the University of California-San Diego; and Angela Wigger, associate professor of international relations at Radboud University discuss the topic: “Antitrust and Industrial Policy, or Antitrust as Industrial Policy?” The full video is embedded below.

Continue reading
Antitrust & Consumer Protection

Fixing the Procedural Infirmities in the DMA’s Draft Implementing Regulation

TOTM Just before Christmas, the European Commission published a draft implementing regulation (DIR) of the Digital Markets Act (DMA), establishing procedural rules that, in the Commission’s own words, . . .

Just before Christmas, the European Commission published a draft implementing regulation (DIR) of the Digital Markets Act (DMA), establishing procedural rules that, in the Commission’s own words, seek to bolster “legal certainty,” “due process,” and “effectiveness” under the DMA. The rights of defense laid down in the draft are, alas, anemic. In the long run, this will leave the Commission’s DMA-enforcement decisions open to challenge on procedural grounds before the Court of Justice of the European Union (CJEU).

Read the full piece here.

Continue reading
Antitrust & Consumer Protection

Your Definitive End-of-Year Global Tech Regulation Wrap-Up: Who’s Doing What, Where, and What to Make of It

TOTM As 2023 draws to a close, we wanted to reflect on a year that saw jurisdictions around the world proposing, debating, and (occasionally) enacting digital . . .

As 2023 draws to a close, we wanted to reflect on a year that saw jurisdictions around the world proposing, debating, and (occasionally) enacting digital regulations. Some of these initiatives amended existing ex-post competition laws. Others were more ambitious, contemplating entirely new regulatory regimes from the ground up.

Read the full piece here.

Continue reading
Antitrust & Consumer Protection